Wednesday, May 11, 1994

Cultural Imperialism Peddles Its Wares

How Multinational Corporations Make A Killing by Marketing Tobacco, Baby Formula, Unsafe Pharmaceuticals, and Pesticides To The Third World

Culture is made up of all the diverse elements that have been created by social interaction and human commerce over the centuries. Culture is not only the systems of education, religion, entertainment and information that exist within societies, it is also "every aspect of our lives...the vehicles we use, the food we eat, the clothes we wear, the health care we receive, and the work we do." (Lowe, p 142). The products we consume help shape our cultures, and it is in this way that marketing and advertising become cultural carriers.

"To create the economic impact of selling goods, advertising operates psychologically, changing attitudes, images, cognitions, feelings, and ultimately, preferences and values. In the mass, across various people and across time, it has not only psychological, but also sociological and cultural effects." (Pollay and Gallagher, p 359).

One of the most obvious channels by which cultural imperialism functions is through advertising and marketing. MNC's (multinational corporations), whose operations transcend national borders but are mostly owned and controlled by stockholders and investors from the rich, industrialized, so-called "Western" nations, spend $200 billion a year to advertise their products around the world. (Bagdikian, p 85). This does not only involve selling products in developed nations such as the U.S., Europe, and Japan, but also NICS's (newly-industrialized countries) such as those in Southeast Asia and the Middle East, and LDC's (less-developed countries), aka the "third world," in Asia, Africa, and Latin America.

As multinational corporations have extended their business operations throughout the world, they have had to become cultural imperialists out of economic necessity. As global corporate competition has become more and more heated, companies can no longer afford to allow NIC's and less developed countries to function simply as areas to be exploited for the extraction of raw materials and the manufacturing of goods destined for consumption in the rich, industrialized world. NIC's and LDC's have been targeted as additional markets for these same goods. "The third world, for all its grinding poverty, is an increasingly profitable market for imported goods." (Bagdikian, p 85). It's ironic - MNC's have greatly expanded their finished product marketing efforts in LDC's where so many of the developed world's products are themselves now assembled.

In order to sell products, a corporation needs markets. Where these markets do not previously exist, as they do in the industrialized nations where multinationals are headquartered, they must be made to exist. The easiest method is to rely on sophisticated advertising and marketing techniques fine-tuned by the experience of a century of industrial capitalism. Immediate new markets are created by selling to the wealthy elites of less developed nations, but these same countries' poorer majorities are also targeted. Essentially, this is what MNC's are doing and have done around the world for the past few decades. They are assisted in their efforts by Western-owned ad agencies whose operations have also become increasingly global in scope.

A series of mergers by Western-owned ad agencies in the late 1980's created several truly global advertising firms. The world's biggest ad agency is now the UK's Saatchi and Saatchi, which merged with New York's Ted Bates Worldwide in 1986. It had U.S. billings of $2.5 billion and world billings of $6 billion in 1991. The next year, three other major agencies merged - Doyle Dane Bernbach Group, BBDO International, and Needham Harper Worldwide. In 1985, these agencies had U.S. billings of $3.7 billion and $5 billion in world billings. (Hachten, p 104). After buying American agencies J. Walter Thompson and Oligivy & Mather, Britain's WPP Group PLC had $2.4 billion in worldwide billings for 1989. (De Mooij and Keegan, p 352).

Creating demand for Western products is made easier by attempts to transplant Western culture to other national settings through media imperialism.

"Television availability is convenient for MNC's transferring modern consumer goods from markets where TV is the major means of promotion. MNC's purchase old American films and TV series...these are then rented to LDC television networks with MNC advertisements inserted." (Hill and Boya, p 258.)

In areas where TV sets are not widely available, MNC's rely on non-traditional advertising methods to popularize Western products.

"Mobile movies are set up in suburban areas outside major LDC cities or in well-populated rural areas. Audiences of many hundreds gather to watch John Wayne, Jerry Lewis, Marx Brothers or Kung Fu films. Between films, advertisements, often 10 to 15 minutes long, demonstrate how to use toothpastes or washing powders and what benefits are derived from them." (Hill and Boya, p 258.)

Since the early 1980s, the giant Western advertising agencies have taken renewed interest in standardizing advertising messages across national and cultural boundaries. "Notwithstanding great economic disparities among nations, certain segments of the population are becoming much more homogeneous across countries." (Rau, p 313). Also known as the global marketing approach, and "first articulated by Harvard marketing professor Ted Levitt" (Eger, p 5), this trend can be traced partially to the continued expansion of multinationals' global business operations. MNC's favor advertising standardization mainly because they want to cut costs. (Kirpalani, Laroche and Darmon, p329).

One obvious result of such standardization has been labeled "linguistic imperialism," or the spread of English and other Western languages to the detriment of indigenous languages.

"The proliferation of languages and dialects in most LDC's - 80 percent of which are multilingual - results in print media using commercial languages like English, French or Spanish or a lingua franca (combination dialect) to maximize their audience." (Hill and Boya, p 251).

It is easy to see this development as a natural one, necessary for any communications to occur in nations with multi-lingual populations. But this ignores its harmful effects. "Without question, much of the wondrous diversity of the world's many cultures and languages is being lost forever." (Hachten, p 88).

Another problem that standardization of cross-cultural marketing creates is the disruption of pre-existing value systems within target societies. "Due to cultural preferences, widespread consumer differences about products persist as do attitudes toward food, beauty, work, play, love, and politics." (Hachten, p 105). The most serious criticism of overly standardized advertising by MNC's is that it is based on Western cultural values that encourage consumption, materialism, self-indulgence, and hedonism. (Pollay and Gallagher, p 370). The Consumer Association of Penang, Malaysia described its concerns this way:

"A worrying trend is the growing influence of negative aspects of Western fashion and culture on the people in the Third World countries, including Malaysia. The (global) advertising industry has created the 'Consumer Culture' which has in fact become our 'National Culture.' Within this cultural system people measure their worth by the size of their house, the make of their car, and the possession of the latest household equipment, clothes, and gadgets." (Frith, p 4).

Critics have also charged that other negative values inherent in Western advertising strengthen negative cultural traditions which already exist in other less developed nations, such as sexism. "The notion that women are indeed stereotyped in advertisements has been given ample empirical support in both the United States and Britain. Recent studies show similar patterns in Australia and Mexico (Gilly, 1988)." (Lysonski and Pollay, p 318). Levels of sexist stereotyping in U.S. advertising are particularly troubling because U.S. ad agencies dominate the newly merged global ad agencies. A 1989 study comparing male/female role portrayals in U.S. and Swedish magazine advertisements found that "U.S. advertisers presented 81.5 percent of the females in a decorative role while Swedish advertisers depicted of 30.7 percent of the females in such a role." (Wiles and Tjernlund, p 264).

"Since many cosmetics MNC's use American brand names overseas (Helena Rubinstein, Max Factor, Revlon, for example), it is likely that MNC's are looking to influence LDC consumers towards American standards of beauty. Given the worldwide distribution of many U.S. movies and TV series, American cosmetics and beauty standards receive significant global exposure." (Hill and Boya, p 260).

In many cases, global marketing has gone beyond simple attempts to transplant Western culture to other national settings and thus create demand for Western products. Multinationals have used consumer product advertising in the third world to sell products to already poverty-stricken populations that neither need nor can afford them. Even worse, some of the MNC's most involved in international marketing seem to focus their third world marketing efforts on the selling of goods that are actually harmful to human health. The sale of many of these products are already restricted to various degrees in Western nations.

Flagrant offenders in this category include the tobacco, baby formula, pharmaceutical, pesticide and chemical industries. This is cultural imperialism at its deadliest.


Tobacco

As the health risks of tobacco use have become known in advanced industrial nations, the world's giant cigarette manufacturers have increasingly targeted consumers in developing nations. Global tobacco use has jumped 75 percent in the past twenty years, although it has been steadily declining in the United States and Western Europe. (Lowe, p 139). And although tobacco use has long been widespread in some developing regions, such as Southeast Asia, smoking has traditionally been a habit confined to adult men. National tobacco monopolies that did little or no advertising controlled the markets in most developing nations. "This was a case where monopolies were a good thing...they tended to be sluggish, inefficient, uninterested in aggressive promotions" (Sesser, p 85). Change would come in the late 1980s.

The U.S. tobacco industry received unprecedented help from the Reagan and Bush Administrations in forcing a series of Asian governments to allow the import and advertising of U.S.-manufactured cigarettes. Under threat of massive U.S. trade retaliation (made possible by Section 301 of the 1974 Trade Act, which gives the
President the power to unilaterally impose tariffs on another country's goods), Japan and Taiwan were forced to open their doors to U.S. tobacco in 1986, South Korea in 1988, and Thailand in 1989. (Sesser, p 85). Since then, tobacco sales have skyrocketed. Sophisticated ad campaigns have reached out to new markets by targeting Southeast Asian teenagers and women.

"According to a Gallup poll cited in a 1990 General Accounting Office (GAO) report, after Korean import restrictions were removed in 1988, smoking rates among male Korean teenagers rose from 18.4 percent in 1988 to 29.8 percent in 1989. Over the same period, the rate among female teenagers rose from 1.6 percent to 8.7 percent." (Multinational Monitor editorial, 1992).

In 1985, American companies exported 18 billion cigarettes to the Pacific Rim; by last year, that figure had risen to 87 billion, or 12 percent of the total U.S. output. In Philip Morris' 1992 annual report, the company stated that over the last year, "In Japan, our volume increased by 5 percent...to account for nearly 12 percent of this large market...Our combined unit sales in Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, the Philippines, Malaysia, and Thailand increased by nearly 20 percent." (Sesser, p 79).

The national tobacco monopolies in these countries responded to competition from the U.S. tobacco industry by developing aggressive marketing campaigns of their own. "Since the Korean market was opened, the Korean monopoly has developed and marketed brands intended for women, known as Lilac, Jade, and Rose." (Multinational Monitor editorial, 1992).

Of these four Southeast Asian countries, only Thailand refused to drop its ad ban against U.S. tobacco advertising, although it agreed to allow U.S. tobacco imports. (Weissman, 1991, p 7). Nevertheless, U.S. tobacco companies still advertise in Thailand, using a new form of global marketing called awareness advertising. "Awareness advertising is the practice of multinational firms buying paid advertising space in a market where the product is either not allowed to be commercially imported for sale or not locally (advertised)." (Rau, p 314).

In Malaysia, the government's ban on tobacco advertising has similarly prevailed despite heavy pressure from the Bush Administration to back down. Malaysia has thus become one of the primary developing nation testing grounds for awareness advertising by the tobacco multinationals.

"The tobacco companies sponsor televised events and use other businesses as fronts to promote their deadly product. Marlboro sponsors the "Marlboro World of Sports." Camel runs a clothing line. The British company Rothmans promotes its Peter Stuyvesant brand with billboards that picture images of the Statue of Liberty, American football players and cheerleaders and use a slogan connecting the brand name Stuyvesant to the magic word "America." Salem runs a music store, Salem Power Station, and a travel company, Salem World, which jointly took out full page advertisements in Malaysian newspapers in the summer of 1993 to promote a contest which had a trip to London to see a U2 concert as its grand prize." (Weissman, 1993, p 7).

Health advocates in many countries are outraged by this form of tobacco marketing.

"The use of images that evoke 'America' is particularly insidious, contends Karen Lewis, manager of tobacco policy resources at the Washington, D.C.-based Advocacy Institute's Smoking Control Advocacy Resource Center, since it preys on poor people's longing for the political freedom and economic advancement popularly associated with the U.S." (Weissman, 1993, p 8).

Tobacco MNC's are also aggressively expanding their marketing operations in Eastern Europe (Weissman, 1992), China (Lewis, p 6), and Latin America. In 1992, a Brazilian tobacco trade group named the Brazilian Cigarette Industry Association, composed of Philip Morris, British American Tobacco, and a handful of smaller companies, successfully lobbied the Brazilian government to overturn ad restriction regulations that would have required warning labels to cover 20% of all tobacco print advertising and banned tobacco product television ads between 6 a.m. and 9 p.m. (Sugarman, p 4).

Philip Morris has rejected proposals from health advocates that it place warning labels on all cigarettes it sells worldwide, even in countries lacking regulations which require such warnings. This is a poignant refutation of the tobacco industry's familiar argument that smoking is a matter of individual choice made by consumers willing to bear the risks. As critics have pointed out, "in third world countries, where there is no information, there is no informed consent. People buy (Philip Morris) products and they just don't know the health risks." (Lowe, p 139).

The risks, of course, are millions of preventable deaths by smoking-related diseases. Using China as the prime example, Richard Peto, a professor of medical statistics and epidemiology at Oxford and an expert on cigarette-induced mortality, gives some horrifying figures.

"The Chinese smoked 500 billion cigarettes in 1978 and 1,700 billion last year (1992)...There are about 420 million people under the age of twenty now living in China. On present smoking patterns, about forty percent will be smokers, or 170 million. The American evidence suggests that if people start smoking and keep going wholeheartedly, something like half will be killed by cigarettes. I don't know what that figure will be like in China, but even if it's thirty percent you're looking at 50 million deaths of people who are now kids." (Sesser, p 80).

Dr. James Mason, who was Assistant Secretary for Health in the Department of Health and Human Services under George Bush but was not allowed to influence cigarette-export policy, put it this way in a 1993 interview.

"Our country has been known for its humanitarian and health-related projects worldwide. This is a hundred and eighty degrees opposite. We're talking about millions of lives - and that totally outweighs and overwhelms what we've accomplished in the humanitarian field. It's outrageous for the United States to allow this misery and suffering to occur." (Sesser, p 79).


Baby Formula

In the 1970s, the world health community identified a significant factor that had caused declining breastfeeding rates in developing nations and a simultaneous rapid increase in infant mortality rates. This factor was the sale of baby formula breastmilk substitutes by a handful of MNC's targeting hospitals and new mothers, primarily in the third world. "Large companies like Nestle and American Home Products were aggressively marketing these products which resulted in the deaths of about one million babies a year from something called 'bottle baby disease'." (Lamy, p 16) The problem with marketing baby formula in developing nations was that:

"For bottle feeding to be safe, there must be clean water, fuel, and facilities to boil the water and sterilize the equipment, adequate income to be able to afford the milk powder and a level of literacy that allows for the mixing, sterilizing instructions to be carefully followed." (Sokol, p 9).

Because these conditions are often non-existent in the third world, "the risk of death for infants who do not breastfeed is 10 to 15 times greater in the first 3 to 4 months of life than for babies who are fed only breastmilk." (Sokol, p 9).

In 1981, the World Health Assembly adopted the final version of a World Health Organization/UNICEF-sponsored International Code of Marketing Breast-milk Substitutes. Following a seven year boycott against Nestle SA, the world's largest producer of substitute baby formula, in 1984 Nestle signed an agreement with boycott organizers pledging to abide by the provisions of this code. Other companies soon followed suit. The code provisions included a ban on any advertising which would idealize bottle feeding, a ban on advertising to the general public, and no promotions in hospitals or to health care workers. Activists thought the battle was over.

However, in 1991, the IBFAN (International Baby Food Action Network) released a detailed report titled "Breaking The Rules 1991," which proved that for the MNC's of this industry, profits still matter more than babies' lives. The IBFAN report documented hundreds of continued code violations by more than eighty global corporations, including Nestle. (Sokol, p 9).

The current worst offenders are Swiss-owned Nestle; Wyeth, a subsidiary of American Home Products; two German companies, Milupa and Hipp; and Meiji, a Japanese corporation. "In Karachi, Pakistan, giant billboards loom over streets and television stations broadcast advertisements beckoning consumers to buy Meiji's infant formulas. Maternity wards all over Asia are decorated with posters of beautiful 'Snow Brand' babies (Snow Brand is another Japanese formula manufacturer)." (Sokol, p 10).

The industry practice of providing hundreds of cartons of free infant formula to third world hospitals is perhaps its most potent marketing weapon, and continues unchecked. It encourages new mothers to begin bottlefeeding their infants immediately. "Hospitals receiving free supplies start babies on formula - at no cost to the hospital or to the mother - but when the mother leaves the hospital, she must buy the expensive formula." (Sokol, p 10). The baby formula MNC's have also attempted to circumvent Code provisions by marketing a product called "follow up" formula. These products are marketed as suitable for babies between the ages of three months and three years. "In North America and Europe, Nestle and its subsidiary Carnation advertise follow-up milks in parenting magazines. Most of the infant formula companies advertise them heavily in professional journals all over the world." (Sokol, p 10).


Pharmaceuticals

The global pharmaceutical companies have long been charged with business practices harmful to developing nations by marketing "useless or even dangerous drugs to people who are sick because they (don't) have enough to eat, no clean water or appropriate housing." (Knaus, p 33). British pharmaceutical corporation Organon markets a drug called Durabolin in the U.K., recommending it be prescribed for osteoporosis in post-menopausal women and aplastic anemia.

"In Pakistan, however, Durabolin is (prescribed) for loss of weight, poor weight gain, and malnutrition in children. Malnutrition and poor weight gain are due to poverty. What is needed is food and not Durabolin, which may produce precocious puberty." (Balasubramaniam, p 25).

Ciba-Geigy is the third largest manufacturer of prescription drugs in the world. It produces Butazolidin and used to make Tenderil, both "non-steroidal anti-inflammatory drugs once widely used for the treatment of arthritis and rheumatism. Their side effects include agranulocytosis, a potentially fatal blood disorder. In 1983, Ciba-Geigy issued an internal memo saying that the drugs had caused the deaths of 1,030 people and seriously injured 4,481 others." (Knaus, p 30).

The company did not withdraw Tanderil from the worldwide market until public pressure forced their hand in 1985. Ciba-Geigy continued selling Butazolidin, supposedly recommending that its use be restricted, but actually employing a double standard in marketing appeals to third world vs. Western doctors and consumers. "In Switzerland, Ciba-Geigy recommends a short one-week therapy with...Butazolidin. This indication of time is non-existent in Mexico." (Knaus, p 31).


Pesticides

International chemical companies have a depressing record of marketing pesticides to the third world that have been previously banned for use in advanced industrial nations. In 1991, Ciba-Geigy was forced to re-purchase over 100,000 gallons of insecticide containing DDT that it had sold to Tanzania, in violation of its own internal company policy prohibiting the sale of banned products to the third world. (Knaus, p 32). In 1993, the British multinational ICA Agrochemicals paid for full page ads that ran in Malaysian newspapers promoting its herbicide paraquat as necessary for a "greener Malaysia." The ad was headlined "Paraquat and nature working in perfect harmony," and went on to claim, "It's a fact. Paraquat is environmentally friendly...ground water, rivers, streams and lakes are not affected" by the chemical. In reality:

"Paraquat has been described by the World Health Organization as one of the world's most deadly chemicals...it is banned in Sweden, Finland, and the Netherlands and restricted for use in Norway, Indonesia, the Philippines, Japan and Turkey...(however), it is one of the biggest selling pesticides internationally and is widely used on plantations throughout the third world. Workers spraying paraquat suffer from vision and skin disorders and experience nausea. Workers' fingernails and toenails fall out as a result of contact with paraquat." (Gozan, p 4).

Ironically, despite Western bans on such pesticides, the harmful effects of their continued sale to the third world boomerang back onto Western consumers when foods grown abroad re-enter advanced industrial nations for sale.


Some Solutions

What, if anything, can be done about global advertising and marketing that function as agents of cultural imperialism?

Multinational corporations now have almost unlimited power to expand their marketing operations around the world. Marketing regulations and restrictions that exist in rich, industrial nations can be circumvented by companies with business operations in third world nations that lack such regulatory structures. Under the Reagan and Bush Administrations, the U.S. government demonstrated its willingness to go to bat for even the most flagrant example of a domestic industry seeking to impose its harmful products on peoples of other countries - the tobacco industry. Such efforts have slowed under the Clinton Administration, but the damage has already been done in regions like the Pacific Rim.

One way to bring about change would be for MNC's to voluntarily stop exploiting third world labor and resources, and thus contribute to true third world economic development that over time would help create living standards high enough to sustain mass consumption of a corporation's products. But this is unlikely to happen. Obviously, the power of multinational corporations will have to be checked by truly international regulatory forces. Unless we move towards a system of world government, possibly based on a strengthened United Nations, this is equally unlikely to happen.

A simultaneous program of sustainable, non-exploitative economic development for the third world, divorced from multinational profits, will also have to occur. This would allow homegrown media systems to emerge in the developing world that could serve as counterweights to the one-way flow of Western culture that now characterizes the global information system, of which global advertising and marketing is an indispensable part. Until such time as these developments come to pass, the world's diversity of cultures and value systems will continue to erode under the onslaught of modern day cultural imperialism.


Works Cited

Ben Bagdikian, "Global Media Corporations Control What We Watch And Read," Utne Reader, July/August 1990, pp 84-89.

Kumariah Balasubramaniam, "A Healthy Drug Policy For the Third World: An Interview with Kumariah Balasubramaniam," Multinational Monitor, December 1992, pp 25-29.

de Mooij, Marieke K., and Warren J. Keegan. Advertising Worldwide, 1991. New York: Prentice Hall.

John M. Eger, "Global Television: An Executive Overview," Columbia Journal of World Business, Fall 1987, pp 5-10.

Katherine T. Frith, "More Than We Bargained For: The Impact of Consumer Culture in Southeast Asia," Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Association for Education in Journalism and Mass Communication (71st, Portland, OR, July 2-5, 1998), June 1, 1988, pp 1-13.

Julie Gozan, "Green Deception," Multinational Monitor, June 1993, p 4.

Hachten, William A., The World News Prism, 3rd ed., 1991. Ames, Iowa: Iowa State University Press.

John S. Hill and Unal O. Boya, "Consumer Goods Promotions in Developing Countries: An Empirical Study," International Journal of Advertising, June 1987, pp 249-264.

V.H. Kirplani, Michel Laroche, and Rene Y. Darmon, "Role of Headquarter Control by Multinationals in International Advertising Decisions," International Journal of Advertising, July 1988, pp 323-333.

Holley Knaus, "Ciba-Geigy: Pushing Pills and Pesticides," Multinational Monitor, April 1993, pp 30-33.

Elaine Lamy, "Challenging Corporate Abuses: An Interview with INFACT's Elaine Lamy," Multinational Monitor, July/Aug 1993, pp 16-19.

Karen Lewis, "China's Tobacco Wars," Multinational Monitor, Jan/Feb 1992, pp 6-12.

Lowe, Janet. The Secret Empire: How 25 Multinationals Rule The World, 1992. Homewood, Illinois: Business One Irwin.

Steven Lysonski and Richard W. Pollay, "Advertising Sexism is Forgiven, But Not Forgotten: Historical, Cross-Cultural and Individual Differences in Criticism and Boycott Decisions," International Journal of Advertising, September 1990, p 317-329.

Multinational Monitor, Editorial, "Tobacco Imperialism," January/February 1992, p 5.

Richard W. Pollay and Katherine Gallagher, "Advertising and Cultural Values: Reflections In The Distorted Mirror," International Journal of Advertising, September 1990, p 359-372.

Pradeep A. Rau, "Awareness Advertising and International Market Segmentation: An Analysis," International Journal of Advertising, June 1987, pp 313-321.

Stan Sesser, "Opium War Redux," The New Yorker, September 13, 1993, pp 78-89.

Ellen Sokol, "A Formula For Disaster," Multinational Monitor, March 1992, p 9-13.

Jim Sugarman, "Tobacco Ad Ban Fight," Multinational Monitor, September 1990, p 4.

Robert Weissman, "Thai Tobacco Tie," Multinational Monitor, January/February 1991, p 7.

Robert Weissman, "The Marlboro Man Goes East," Multinational Monitor, January/February 1992, pp 31-34.

Robert Weissman, "Promoting The Tobacco Myth," Multinational Monitor, November 1993, pp 7-8.

Charles R. Wiles and Anders Tjernlund, "A Comparison of Role Portrayal of Men and Women in Magazine Advertising in the USA and Sweden," International Journal of Advertising, October 1991, p 259-267.

Sunday, May 1, 1994

Declining Citizen Participation in U.S. Politics

   
   

Editor's note: Some things have changed, but root causes remain

The following paper was written in the spring of 1994 - before the rise of the internet, before Newt Gingrich's Republican takeover of Congress, and before George W. Bush stole the 2000 election and gave the American public fresh reasons to doubt that their votes count. Re-reading it now (trying to keep my eyes from glazing over whenever the kind of jargon required by public policy professors pops up, like "intervening variables"), I was struck by what a depressing picture it paints.

It's not all doom and gloom - see the section on Prospects for Future Reform, which lays out a host of worthy policy changes that if enacted, would help turn things around. But this paper definitely could have been subtitled "Reasons Why Our Country is So F-ed Up," and much remains relevant today.


DECLINING CITIZEN PARTICIPATION IN U.S. POLITICS



I. INTRODUCTION

Why are so many citizens alienated from political life in 1990s America? It is undeniable that popular participation in government is currently low at all levels - national, state, and even local. Public opinion polls and research consistently reveal astounding attitudinal levels of cynicism and alienation among U.S. citizens (Appendix I). We take for granted that ours is the world's leading democracy (Piven and Cloward 3), yet Americans vote in lower numbers than citizens of almost every other rich, industrialized nation (Appendix II). Of the 190 million adult Americans currently eligible to vote, approximately half (95 million) have participated in national, presidential elections during the last twenty years (Teixeira 6). Turnout figures for the 1992 presidential election show 104 million Americans cast ballots for president, a higher number than in any election since 1968 (Clymer A11). Yet this still represents only 55% of the total eligible electorate!

Current turnout rates are ten percent less than levels of the 1950s and 1960s, when presidential turnout hovered between 62-65% of eligible Americans (Piven and Cloward 161), and thirty percent less than average turnout levels during much of the nineteenth century (Appendix III). Voters have always turned out in lesser numbers for elections below the presidential level, but in the last twenty years turnout here has become much lower. Congressional race turnouts in off-year elections since 1974 have ranged from a high of 40.5% (1982) to a low of 36.3% (1986), as compared with nearly 50% during the 1960's (Teixeira 6). Obviously, our "low turnout society (1960s) has been turned into an even lower turnout society (1990s) by these trends" (Teixeira 6).


II. WHY DECLINING PARTICIPATION LEVELS ARE UNHEALTHY FOR U.S. DEMOCRACY

When reduced numbers of voters participate in local, state, and especially national elections, it greatly increases the possibility that apparent electoral choices may not be representative of the truly popular will. Many political theorists think about this issue in slightly different terms, usually framing the problem as one of democratic legitimacy (Gilmour and Lamb 134-140). They feel declining participation could erode the unspoken consent of most citizens in support of the overall U.S. political system, if it has not yet already, and "the results of such delegitimation could range from generalized social and political disorganization" (Teixeira 101) to gridlocked government and the popular devaluation of public service.

Other observers stress that "democracy is not only the most humane form of government, it is also the most fragile. It depends not only for its legitimacy but also for its health and well-being on the involvement of the governed" (Gans 529). In a 1990 report, the Committee for the Study of the American Electorate outlined other commonly identified negative societal effects of declining participation levels. They include (1) the danger of policymaking by special interests; (2) the danger to volunteerism and social integration; (3) the danger of a bleak future since younger voters are participating at the lowest levels of all; (4) the threat to political cohesion and the formation of national consensus; (5) the threat to government accountability and the danger of demagoguery; and (6) the danger to orderly process (CSAE, 583-584).

Of all these dangers, the gravest is the surrender of the public interest to private, special interests which is facilitated by declining participation. Only an extremely limited number of Americans influence public policy through methods other than voting. Barring unusual circumstances, only an activist minority becomes involved in political campaigns (19%), donates to candidates (22%), or lobbies government officials (Raasch 1). Due to the influence of money on today's political system (Povich 3), the citizen activists likely to exert the most influence on public policy are members of the upper middle class or the wealthy. Some ordinary citizens do make their voices heard by writing letters to newspapers or to elected officials, or participating in public opinion surveys, but the influence these measures have in shaping public policy is limited. Throughout the 1980s, polls consistently showed public opposition to the policies of Ronald Reagan, yet his policies remained consistent (Mitchell 521-522).

Thus, it is even more important for citizens of all socioeconomic backgrounds to vote. Yet most Americans who vote differ in important respects from those who do not.

"Voters are better off and better educated, and non-voters are poorer and less well educated. Modest variations notwithstanding, this has been true for most of the twentieth century and has actually worsened in the last two decades. In sum, the American electorate overrepresents those who have more, and underrepresents those who have less" (Piven and Cloward 4).

Over time, declining levels of mass voter participation have thus ensured public policy formation in the U.S. would be heavily influenced by a tiny minority of the population, generally our nation's wealthy elites, special interest groups, and private, large-scale economic interests. Public policy is made with these special interests in mind, and designed to serve the public interest only as an afterthought.

Sadly, particularly flagrant instances of policymaking which disregard the public interest seem more prevalent than ever in recent years. Some examples include the Reagan-era deregulation of the U.S. broadcasting industry which accelerated corporate concentration of ownership of the media (Lee and Soloman 71); national transportation policies that have neglected public transportation in order to preserve automobile industry profits (Brown 115); national energy policies that have similarly ignored alternative energy research out of subservience to the oil industry (D.H. Davis 269- 270); recent congressional passage of NAFTA without concern for its long-term contributions to continued American deindustrialization (Brecher 685); on-going, unquestioned levels of U.S. military and economic aid to human rights-violating nations such as El Salvador (Fish and Sganga 12), Guatemala (Lafaber 359), Indonesia (Pilger 551) and Israel (Findley ix-xvii); and the 1981 Reagan tax cuts for the wealthiest one percent of Americans which have "cost the public more than $1 trillion since 1978, according to Citizens For Tax Justice" (Extra!Update 2).


III. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

Rule by the elite is not a new development in U.S. history. Since colonial times, American elites have maintained tight controls on who would be allowed to have a voice in public affairs. From property voting restrictions to denying the franchise to women and black Americans, too much popular participation in government has long been discouraged. The Constitutional Convention of 1787 accomplished many things, but:

"It did not provide for popular elections, except in the case of the House of Representatives, where the qualifications were set by the state legislatures (which required property-holding for voting in almost all the states), and excluded women, Indians, slaves...however, the problem of democracy in post-Revolutionary society was not Constitutional limitations on voting. It lay deeper...in the division of society into rich and poor. For if some people had great wealth and great influence; if they had the land, the money, the newspapers, the church, the educational system - how could voting, however broad, cut into such power?" (Zinn 95).

Nevertheless, American elites have displayed continued unwillingness to take such a chance. As newly enfranchised former slaves and an increasingly urbanized working class began to vote their class interests in the late nineteenth century, elites worked to enact structural electoral changes which brought high levels of popular mobilization back down. In the North, these changes were made under the guise of "reforms" designed to prevent fraud, such as outlawing the party ballot and instituting personal voter registration (Kousser 51). In the South, measures such as the poll tax and literacy tests were passed explicitly to take the franchise back from black citizens. They also had the effect of disfranchising poor Southern whites (Piven and Cloward 83).

Although the legal forms of these voting restrictions in the South have disappeared, their legacy remains. Southern blacks in some communities still face fraud, intimidation, and legal efforts to slow the full realization of their political strength. In 1990, state Republican party officials in North Carolina mailed 150,000 postcards containing misleading and fraudulent information to black voters only a week before the Gantt-Helms U.S. Senate election (Edsall A13).

"Reports persist of subtle economic intimidation against black voters, particularly in sections of the Mississippi Delta and rural Georgia. There have been numerous accounts, sometimes in court, of plants that 'happened' to close late on election day and of landowners who increased their election-day hires, only to keep those workers in the fields until after polls had closed. There remains, said Gerald Jones in 1985 (head of the Justice Department's voting section), a sense among poor blacks in some plantation counties that 'if you want to eat, you better not cross Mr. So-and-So' by voting" (Edds 14-15).

Overall Southern voting levels still lag behind the rest of the country (Appendix II). Furthermore, while Southern black voting levels did rise dramatically in the decade following passage of the Voting Rights Act in 1965, the new, post-1968 decline in voting levels has affected Americans of all races and socioeconomic backgrounds in all other regions of the country (Hadley 60).

In the North, most of the voter registration procedures originally implemented to curb working class participation still exist, and their effects continue to be felt. In 1972, the middle class voted at one and a half times the rate of working class Americans, 77 percent versus 52 percent (Burnham 114). The overall percentage of Americans who were registered to vote in 1984 was estimated to be only between 63 and 64 percent (Piven and Cloward 258).

If presidential majorities can be delivered by little more than a quarter of the electorate (assuming 50% turnouts), and our Congress is composed of individuals elected on average by less than one fifth of all eligible voters (35-40% turnout levels), how representative of truly popular wishes is our system of government?

We are entering what some proclaim to be the brave new world of the information age. Its promise is based largely on hopes that still-theoretical technologies will give us "interactive communication highways," bringing the power of information within reach of everyone (Elmer-Dewitt 58). But will every citizen have equal access to such power if participatory democracy no longer exists in America? Or if it never really has? For the long-term health of our democracy, we must address these issues now.


IV. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

It is a complex undertaking to try to diagnose the root causes of trends as endemic as modern day political alienation in America and declining levels of citizen participation in U.S. government. A realization that more inclusive citizen participation has been discouraged by American elites ever since our nation's very beginnings makes this policy dilemma even more systemic, and one so deeply ingrained in our nation's fabric as to perhaps be unalterable.

On the most basic level, citizen participation can be measured by voter turnout rates. As previously shown, citizens can influence public policy through methods other than voting, but voting "has been shown in a number of surveys to be a lowest common denominator act - people who do not vote are not likely to participate in any other form of social, civic, or political activity." (Gans 528). It is the minimal contribution citizens can make and still have some say in the direction of public affairs. Thus, fluctuating voter turnout rates are the dependent variable my research will examine.

Many policy variables influence U.S. voter turnout rates. I have identified three as the most important: (1) levels of civic education, (2) financing of elections, and (3) structural electoral rules, including voter registration procedures. These are also the variables most directly subject to policy changes aimed at boosting levels of citizen participation by increasing voter turnout rates.

Two further factors are relevant to both historically low levels of popular participation and the more recent, post-1968 decline. They are (1) the technologically-driven, ever-increasing complexity of modern life in America, and (2) vast disparities in wealth between rich and average Americans. These factors are more historically constant and less subject to change through policy reform.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section V discusses how these three variables and two historical factors are interrelated, including my principal hypothesis for reform and a look at other intervening variables. Section VI examines each of the five in detail. Section VII offers specific policy recommendations designed to reverse the trend of declining citizen participation each of these five factors contributes to, and general conclusions pertaining to the political feasibility of future reform.


V. RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN PRIMARY AND INTERVENING VARIABLES

A. Principal Hypothesis For Reform

If reforms are instituted such as the provision of more focused civic education/information in schools and on television, public campaign financing laws, and structural electoral reform in the form of less frequent election scheduling, the adoption of majority preferential voting, and liberalized voter registration procedures, voter turnout and citizen participation will increase. A more informed and active public will be better able to identify policies truly in the public's best interest, now partially obscured by the increased complexities of modern society.

This will lead to the election of lawmakers dedicated to the public interest before wealthy, private interests. Over the long term, such a revival of popular representation will hopefully contribute to a redress of the vast inequities between rich and poor which exist in our country and around the world.

B. Other Intervening Variables

In addition to the previously mentioned five primary factors behind declining levels of participation, there are other contextual, intervening, and control variables which somewhat muddy any analysis of this issue.

These include (1) the influence on participation rates by public perceptions of the existing class of lawmakers and high-level political leaders; (2) other varying socioeconomic characteristics of voters besides education and income, including race and age; (3) the behavior of institutions who play a direct role in policy implementation regarding citizen participation, such as local or state election boards or offices of secretaries of state; (4) the structural nature of information mediums by which citizens receive information about politics, i.e., newspapers, television; (5) the levels of political education necessary for citizens to feel they "know enough about the issues to vote," partially dependent on the levels of complexity involved in understanding particular social or political issues; (6) the relative sense of public drama and attention surrounding particular elections; (7) differing levels of ambition on the parts of candidates to seek office; (8) candidates' differing abilities to wage campaigns that effectively mobilize voters; (9) special interests who subsidize efforts to influence public policy, or more specifically, to affect citizen participation rates, and (10) citizens' relative levels of mobility, determining how rooted or connected they are to the political life of individual communities.

C. Relationships Between Variables

Low levels of civic education, a campaign financing system biased towards wealthy interests, overly frequent elections, the two party bias of winner-take-all voting, and restrictive voter registration procedures all function to reduce voter turnout levels. Their impact is compounded by the more historically constant factors of technologically-driven, ever-increasing complexity in American life, and the vast disparities in wealth which exist between rich and average Americans.

Of the ten other variables previously identified, several can be classified as contextual ones, directly related (as either causes or effects) to these initial five variables. They also function to reduce turnout. These include (1) public perceptions of the existing class of lawmakers and high-level political leaders as out of touch with the problems of average Americans; (2) the fact that young, poor, and minority citizens in America all tend to vote less than their older, richer, white peers, which could change if voter registration procedures were liberalized, access to education broadened, and income disparities reduced; (4) the shift from newspapers to television as the primary information medium by which citizens receive information about politics, leading to a less informed public; and (5) the increasing levels of political education necessary for citizens to feel they "know enough about the issues to vote," due in part to the increasingly complex nature of modern day life.

Most of the others should be more correctly labeled intervening variables. These affect turnout rates relatively independently of the primary five factors we have identified, but would still be affected by certain reforms involving these five factors.

They include: (6) the relative sense of public drama and attention surrounding particular elections, which would be affected by reforms leading to increased multiparty competitiveness; (7) differing levels of ambition on the parts of candidates to seek office; (8) candidates' differing abilities to wage campaigns that effectively mobilize voters; and (9) the increasing number of wealthy special interests who subsidize efforts to influence public policy, or more specifically, to affect citizen participation rates. These last three intervening variables would all be affected by campaign finance reform.

Finally, variable (10) - citizens' relative levels of mobility, i.e., how rooted or connected they are to the political life of individual communities - which would function less as a barrier to participation if voter re-registration became automatic when people move, as part of an liberalization of voter registration procedures.

The only true control variable is (3) - the existence of state and local election boards jealous of their turf who will tend to resist any liberalizing reforms involving voter registration. These bureaucrats have overseen a system of restricted access to the vote for decades, and thus can be expected to display some inertia when forced to implement reforms, no matter how slight.

The relationships between many of the variables in our model are circular. For example, when registration requirements are liberalized, more people will vote, including the young, poor, minority voters and highly mobile citizens. This will in turn lead to the election of public officials more directly concerned with the welfare of the overall community. Over the long term, this may allow the enactment of policies that reduce income disparities by eliminating poverty levels.


VI. FIVE PRIMARY FACTORS BEHIND DECLINING CITIZEN PARTICIPATION

A. Increasing Complexity of Society

The first factor relevant to declining participation levels is a relatively historically constant one. A belief in progress and technology has always been a central article of faith for most Americans (Noble 3). Subsequently, technological developments have long been accepted as natural and inevitable and almost every successive generation of Americans has experienced a technologically-driven increasing complexity of life (Slater 128-130). This march of progress has intensified a hundred-fold since the industrial revolution of the late nineteenth century, and in the process shaped a nation which would be as alien to our ancestors as another planet might be to us. The technological changes that have transformed America in the twentieth century have had almost limitless implications for our lives and the nature of our democracy. Regarding only one aspect of life, the field of communications, consider simply "when one considers pop music, radio, newspapers, magazines, computers, and video games - in addition to TV - we are exposed to more mass media messages in one day than our grandparents saw in a month" (J. Davis 2).

A related factor is the decline of community institutions such as churches, schools, and labor unions in the lives of U.S. citizens. "The institutional base of American society has atrophied...traditional institutions no longer stand for what they once did" (Gans 535). Another is the decline in what social scientists call the "social connectedness" of ordinary citizens, stemming from greater social isolation, increased divorce rates and greater personal mobility (Appendix IV). Today, the average American will move seven times over the course of their life. Each year, approximately 20% of Americans change residences (Weiss 30).

The root causes of social problems existing in our country today are increasingly intertwined and thus harder to understand than problems may have seemed (or actually been) in the past. Thus, there is not only "growing confusion in our society...(but) growing confusion about how to deal with it" (Gans 528). Many people look around them and see a world spinning out of control, with mounting social problems and signs of moral, physical, and societal decay evident everywhere. The revival of American religious fundamentalism seen in the 1970s and 1980s is one direct manifestation of increased alienation from the complexities of modern day life (Crawford 159-164).

B. Disparities In Wealth

The second historically constant factor to keep in mind is the relatively large disparities in personal wealth between America's very rich and the rest of us. "The dirty little secret of our country is that most Americans don't have enough money" (Harrington 26). "One percent of our nation owns a third of the wealth. The rest is distributed in such a way as to turn those in the 99% against each other" (Zinn 571).

"A study estimating U.S. wealth distribution for 1962 by means of a detailed survey of a large sample of households found that the top 0.5 percent of "consumer units" (families and single individuals living alone) had 25.8 percent of the wealth. The top 1 percent had 34 percent, the top 10 percent had 62 percent, and the top 30 percent held about 85 percent" (Domhoff 42).

Politics has a lot to do with the distribution of wealth in a society, and resentment develops in the mass consciousness when we are shown an idealized good life on television and in the movies which is out of financial reach for most Americans. The current average American income is approximately $36,000 (Teixeira 35). Measured only against today's costs of sending a child to college, it is not hard to see why more and more middle class Americans feel they are losing ground. Current average annual tuition rates at American four-year colleges and universities now top $6,000 for public and $20,000 for private schools (Stewart A5, H. Anderson 66).

Although income disparities have long been a relatively constant feature of American life, post-World War Two prosperity raised living standards for an unprecedented number of citizens (Leuchtenburg 48-49). However, the rise of a global economy has caused U.S. manufacturing jobs to be shipped overseas, witnessed corporate downsizing that eliminates white collar jobs by the thousands, and meant that recent U.S. job creation has occurred primarily in the low-paid service sector(Brecher 685-686). These developments have eroded middle class prosperity (Appendix IV). Real wages for the vast majority of Americans have remained stagnant for two decades, and within the past few years have actually declined back to levels of the mid-1960s (Chomsky 412). As for the working poor, recent census figures show that in 1992, 18% of the nation's full-time workers earned less than the poverty level ($13,091 a year for a family of four), compared with 12% in 1979 (DePerle A10).

"As the 1980s became the 1990s, many who had become accustomed to middle-class living standards suddenly found their own well-being threatened and worried about how their children would manage to make their way in an increasingly competitive world economy" (Dionne 13).

A 1991 opinion poll "found people agreeing by an 84% to 13% margin that 'in recent years, the rich have been getting richer, and it's been harder for middle income and working families to get by'" (Parenti 103). The response of many who feel the system has abandoned them by ignoring their economic interests has been a personal abandonment of the system through the refusal to vote. As shown by the more than 19 million votes received by independent presidential candidate Ross Perot in 1992(Clymer A11), in the absence of real reform, only under exceptional circumstances will these non-voters be motivated to resume participation.

According to National Election Study data, "lower-class groups of Americans...(have) showed the greatest turnout declines" (Piven and Cloward 161). Between 1964 and 1980, the percentage of unemployed voters dropped from 58% to 41.2%, a decline of 16.8 percent. The corresponding turnout drop for employed citizens was from 73% to 61.8%, or a 11.2 percent decrease (Piven and Cloward 162). Between 1960 and 1988, voter turnout rates for the lowest-income third of Americans fell from 68.5% to 52.8%, or by 15.7 percent. Turnout rates for the wealthiest third of Americans dropped from 87.2% to 83.6%, a decline of only 3.6 percent (Appendix V).

"The lack of participation on the part of the poor may be the result of a rational assessment of a hopeless political situation created by the rich...in the postwar period the people who didn't vote were the poor, the minorities, the less educated, the lower-paid strata of the working class...they did not see any party or leader who made it worth their while to get involved" (Harrington 245-246).

Since working class citizen turnouts were already kept down by the disfranchising methods previously outlined, these more recent declines are especially troubling.

C. Levels Of Civic Education

The first variable conducive to policy reform and relevant to declining participation levels is public ignorance, or rather, the state of enforced public ignorance people are kept in. Time and time again, non-voters give "not knowing enough about the issues" as a primary reason for not voting (Teixeira 11). Unless people are aware of how political choices affect their lives and which political candidates (if any) truly represent their economic and ideological interests, they will lack motivation to participate in public affairs by casting a vote or any by other means.

We face a particularly acute set of obstacles to achieving and maintaining high levels of civic education in our country. One is the historic treatment of U.S. mass media as profit-making entities (Bagdikian xx) instead of social institutions dedicated to keeping the public informed. Another factor is the persistent strain of anti-intellectualism in American culture (Hofstadter 3-9) which endures because of unequal, income-based access to education at all levels of the system, from public schools funded by widely varying local property taxes to universities with sky-high tuition rates.

In 1950, only 15% of Americans had attended some college. By 1988 this figure had more than doubled, to 38%, but the number of college graduates was only 19% (Teixeira 83). College is still an upper-level form of education available only to a minority of the population. In 1988 a full 62% of all U.S. citizens had high school or lower-level educations: 39.3% of them high school graduates, 22.6% without diplomas (Appendix VI).

Just as there have been increases in college education levels, these high school graduation figures represent a marked increase over high school graduation rates of thirty or forty years ago (Appendix IV). 77.4% of Americans had high school diplomas by 1988, compared with only 51% in 1960 (Teixeira 34). But according to College Board statistics, mean SAT scores have slipped steadily over the past forty years (Grossman 3D), which partially offsets the impact of rising high school graduation rates. During this same period, the increasing complexity of modern life has made it necessary for U.S. citizens to attain higher levels of education just to keep abreast of social and technological change. As America has shifted to a high-tech, high-skilled, service-based economy (Brecher 687), in many cases higher education levels have become essential to simply keeping one's job. "By the mid-seventies, most (college students) realized a liberal-arts bachelor's degree was worth about as much as a high school diploma of a generation ago" (Harrington 63).

In any case, rising education levels have been offset by the fact that over the years, the U.S. public consistently has been kept poorly informed by the for-profit, increasingly corporate-owned mass media as to the true nature of forces shaping our lives and possible solutions to our society's problems (Parenti 1-8). Twin factors of corporate control and advertiser influence create inherent biases in the supposedly "objective" news we see and hear. Most channels of mass communication in our country are organized and owned by large media corporations (Bagdikian 4). Some of these corporate entities are themselves directly owned by other conglomerates, such as General Electric, the company that owns NBC. Most are controlled by boards of directors whose members also own and control other large, non-media corporations - the so-called "interlocking directorates" of the corporate ruling class.

"The boards of directors of the Big Three (networks) are composed of executives, lawyers, financiers, and former government officials who represent the biggest banks and corporations in the U.S., including military and nuclear contractors, oil companies, agribusiness, insurance and utility firms" (Lee and Soloman 81).

Nearly all of the mass media are involved in business relationships with other large corporations who pay them to advertise their products. On average, magazines derive 50% of their total revenue from ads; newspapers approximately 75-80%; and network television, 100% (Dominick 126, 146).

Corporate control and advertiser influence over the mass media cannot help but influence the selection and presentation of news (Bagdikian 15, 138). If news stories surface which reflect badly on companies owning mass media outlets, the stories will be ignored or minimized (Cirino 234).

The existence of interlocking directorates tying media boards of directors directly to dozens of other non-media corporations (Parenti 29) extends this aura of preferential journalistic treatment to business interests far beyond those who exercise direct ownership power over a particular media entity (such as GE's power over NBC). The mass media's economic need to maintain advertising revenues by staying in good favor with corporate advertisers has made the entire corporate system into a "sacred cow" (Lee and Soloman 75). Occasional instances of blatant corporate wrongdoing, consumer fraud, or worker exploitation may be publicized, but (a) only enough to make people think the mass media are fulfilling their adversarial, public watchdog role, and (b) infrequently enough to perpetuate the illusion that such scandals are rare exceptions in a smoothly running corporate system rather than being the rule in a badly functioning, exploitative one (Parenti 69).

The gradual dumbing effect of television on people has also played a part in offsetting the effects of increased education levels and decreasing participation in numerous other ways. According to some media critics:

"Television has served to atomize our society; weaken our institutions; reduce participation by making people spectators and consumers rather than involved participants; decreased reading, comprehension and conversation; and increased public confusion. It gives (us) information in undifferentiated blips and by highlights of the most visually exciting" (Gans 536).

Whether one agrees with this analysis or not, it is undeniable we are watching more television than ever before - by the late eighties, more than seven hours in average daily viewing time per U.S. household (Daley 1). The television we watch does little to provide meaningful information to most Americans. "In the United States, roughly 97% of prime-time broadcast TV is devoted to entertainment programming. Americans are entertainment rich and knowledge poor" (Elgin 70). Television has also offset rising education levels in a structural sense, by discouraging daily newspaper reading. "Daily household (newspaper) penetration has dropped from 97.9% in 1970 to 66.3% in 1990" (Ungaro 3-4).

The true picture may be even bleaker than already painted. Despite the previously quoted official figures regarding education levels, business sources and the most recent, comprehensive, U.S. Dept. of Education four-year study of adult American literacy rates both estimate that approximately 44% of our population can today be classified as functionally illiterate (Celis A1).

D. Financing Of Elections

The second primary factor affecting participation rates is the structure of our campaign financing system. Decreasing levels of public education, coupled with a simultaneous explosion in financial resources necessary to win election to major public offices has resulted in the election of a whole class of public officials more devoted to serving wealthy, private interests than the public interest. Historically, most big political money went into presidential campaigns. After campaign financing reforms of 1974 set up public subsidies for the presidential campaign in general elections, the quest for direct influence over public policy shifted to congressional races. Between 1974 and 1986, the average cost of a House incumbent's campaign increased from $56,539 to $334,222 and the average cost for incumbent Senators jumped from $555,714 to $3,303,518. (Smith 155).

"The money chase means Senate and House members court big donors at the expense of little ones. They especially seek donations from influential political action committees where contributions are measured in thousands of dollars...particularly in the U.S. House, where members must run every two years, a shadowy network of special interests has evolved to finance congressional campaigns, with most of these contributions going to incumbents" (Povich 2).

Campaign costs have skyrocketed for two reasons. The first is that media time for political advertising must be purchased at the exorbitant rates charged for private advertising. Local stations are spotty in their compliance with the FCC's lowest rate charge rule, which supposedly mandates stations to charge political candidates the lowest possible ad rates. In 1990, U.S. television stations made estimated revenues of between $230 million and $300 million from the sale of political ads (Flint 27). The increased reliance of campaigns on television advertising has also worsened the sound bite nature of modern politics by allowing little opportunity for real debate to occur on issues. "Television whittles the substance of politics down to 30-second spots, often attacks on opponents, giving the electorate a bad taste for politics" (Povich 1).

The second reason for ridiculously high campaign costs has been previously alluded to - the control of Congress by special interest money. A 1991 Los Angeles Times study billed as "the most comprehensive study of campaign spending ever undertaken" (Fritz and Morris 1), found of the nearly $200 million spent by Senate candidates in the 1990 election cycle, 35% was spent on advertising and media consultants. House candidates spent only 25% of their funds on advertising.

"The Times' findings tend to support the view of critics of the campaign finance system, who contend the cost of elections is not growing because of any single expenditure but because special interests are willing to supply candidates with more and more money" (Fritz and Morris 1).

Lax campaign regulations allow corporations and other private interests to form political action committees (PAC's) and contribute too much to candidates, sometimes by "bundling" (Smith 258-259) large contributions from many executives of one firm together to evade PAC spending limits. The funds they provide flow mostly to incumbents, not challengers, which also deters real competition in elections. The money chase necessarily restricts the field of candidates who can afford to seek public office to the wealthy or those whose campaigns are financed by wealthy special interests.

In this instance, though, Lincoln's maxim that "you can't fool all of the people all of the time" comes into play. Big money televised propaganda barrages using 30-second political attack ads may often prevent people from realizing which candidates would best represent their interests during the final, crucial few weeks of hard fought election campaigns. But during the intervals between elections, when elected officials have to govern, it becomes slightly harder to keep people from realizing they're losing out. Sooner or later, it begins to sink in that decisions are being made which time and time again leave the public interest out in the cold.

Thus, negative public perceptions of the existing political class generalizes to an overall distrust for government and negatively affects participation rates.

E. Structural Electoral Rules

The third and final variable impacting participation rates is the system of electoral rules which governs how democracy functions at the level of the voting booth. Many aspects of these rules are biased in favor of low levels of citizen participation, including overly frequent elections, the winner-take-all method of U.S. electoral competition which functions to keep smaller third parties from challenging the two party system, gerrymandered districts, and personal voter registration requirements.

Too-frequent elections

Voting theorists have formed hypotheses about turnout rates by analyzing both the costs and benefits of voting (Teixeira 11). From this perspective, the more frequently elections are scheduled, the higher the costs of voting as an activity become for individual citizens.

Problems arise because unlike most liberalizing electoral changes of the past few decades, many states have shifted their election calendars and now hold elections more frequently than they did in the past (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 565). Most local and some state elections have been moved to non-Congressional (odd-numbered) years. This was done in the name of increasing voter awareness about local elections, out of a fear election day schedules had become too cluttered. Ironically, it has become yet another factor in maintaining a permanent election cycle that dilutes the overall importance of voting in people's minds. The relative weights of these tradeoffs are not immediately clear.

Furthermore, many municipalities now have the authority to schedule special elections for local offices at will. The combined effects of these developments have been the creation of a state-by-state, city-by-city patchwork of erratic voting schedules. In April, 1992 testimony before a N.C. legislative commission on voter participation, State Board of Elections executive director Alex Brock referred to the need for reform in this area:

"North Carolina, from my vantage point, simply places an unnecessary burden upon its voting citizens by permitting elections to be called with erratic frequency...it is a sad commentary when some of our elected officials consistently call special elections just before or after a countywide or citywide election, regularly scheduled, has been conducted." (LRC Appendix I-3).

Winner-take-all

America's winner-take-all method of electoral competition presents far greater obstacles to popular participation. It is also described as a first-past-the-post structure of competition. Except for scattered local experiments with alternative voting methods, this method of competition exists at all levels of the system.

"Where electoral districts are...winner-take-all, voters supporting the minority side in an unbalanced (lopsided) district will have reduced incentive to cast a ballot (as will party organizations to mobilize these voters)...for example, Democratic presidential voters in a heavily Republican U.S. state." (Teixeira 15).

Thus, at the presidential level the electoral college functions to reduce voter incentive in the same way winner-take-all, single-member districts work at the Congressional level.

In addition, winner-take-all voting effectively blocks nearly all third-party electoral challenges. In any three-way race where a third party candidate runs against a Democrat and Republican, the third party candidate must possess pre-existing high levels of support to neutralize the historic advantages enjoyed by the two major parties under the status quo of a strong two party system. Otherwise, potential supporters of the third-party challenge actually have negative incentive to vote for their preferred candidate, since in all likelihood it will only mean splitting the vote and elevating their least desirable choice to office.

This creates almost insurmountable obstacles for smaller parties to overcome, and necessarily leads to a shrunken spectrum of popular representation. Democratic and Republican candidates enjoy huge advantages against all challengers. Grassroots mobilization from outside the two-party system is stifled, which could otherwise increase participation (Teixeira 17). Those in favor of this status quo usually argue America is such a fractious, pluralistic country that representative democracy can only function if elected officials are charged with enacting broad consensus policies. But as the system now functions, all Americans are not being adequately represented.

Gerrymandering

The creation of gerrymandered districts is also a structural factor that limits electoral competitiveness is the modern era (Mitchell 523). Once every decade, state legislators are have direct control over the redistricting of their own state legislative districts and any congressional district boundaries within their individual states. This is done to reflect any geographic population shifts of the previous decade. The development of sophisticated geographic/demographic computer software has made it increasingly possible for these legislators to tailor districts to their best election advantage, or to help other party allies retain their seats.

This has further increased the ability of incumbent elected officials to remain in power. However, state legislators are not about to relinquish their redistricting power to any other authority. Therefore, this factor should be considered a relatively historically constant one that will always contribute to the power of incumbency, no matter how much citizen voter turnout increases or how many responsive public officials are elected.

Voter Registration

Many critics of the U.S. electoral process have concluded that of these four major structural flaws (overly frequent elections, winner-take-all electoral competition, gerrymandering, and voter registration requirements), an obstacle-laden system of personal voter registration reduces participation the most (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 567; CSAE 585; Teixeira 106).

Approximately two-thirds of Americans are registered to vote (Piven and Cloward 258). Once people are registered, they vote at relatively high rates regardless of age or education levels (Appendix V). Critics point out "the U.S. is the only major democracy where government assumes no responsibility for helping citizens cope with voter registration requirements" (Piven and Cloward 17). Voting in the United States is a two-step process in which the first step, getting registered to vote, is not as easy as it might seem. In most other rich, industrialized nations, voter registration is automatic. Great Britain and Canada keep their voting rolls updated through national canvasses, government run and conducted annually (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 562). This helps explain why U.S. voting levels rank low by international comparison (Appendix II).

Since 1960, substantial revisions have been made in statewide voter registration systems. The pace of reform has speeded significantly in the past decade.

Important changes include:

"(1) the abolition of poll taxes; (2) the abolition of literacy tests; (3) the formal prohibition of discrimination within the registration process; (4) the increased availability of bilingual registration materials; (5) the large increase in the number of states permitting registration by mail; (6) the sharp decline in the length of state residency requirements, from a year or more in most states in 1960 to the current, almost uniform level of a month or less; (7) the movement of closing dates - that is, the last date one can register to vote in a given election - closer to the date the election is held; and (8) the implementation of minimum national standards for absentee registration" (Teixeira 29).

More recently, the National Voter Registration Act of 1993, the so-called "Moter-Voter" bill (Appendix X), was signed into law by President Clinton on May 20, 1993 (McNeely 21A). This legislation requires states to provide voter registration at driver's license bureaus and other federal or state agencies, including welfare offices, disability service offices, and military recruiting centers. It also extends mail registration to all fifty states, and prohibits the "purging" of voters from voting rolls simply for failure to vote. Prior to its passage, twenty-five states had no "moter voter" programs, twenty-three states prohibited mail registration, and all but nine states purged citizens from voter registration rolls after an average of three years' failure to vote (Appendix VII).

Important as these reforms have been, they still leave much progress to be made.

As part of the log-rolling that preceded passage of the "Moter Voter" Act, concessions were made to Senate Republicans. Mandated registration at unemployment agencies was dropped from the bill and mandated registration at military recruitment offices added. Mandated welfare agency-based registration was included in the legislation only after an outcry on the part of progressive groups, who argued convincingly that "motor voter" programs by themselves would expand the electorate without overcoming its upward class bias. In 1983, 93% of the 31 million adults in households with incomes over $40,000 had driver's licenses, compared with only 47% of the 36 million adult Americans with household incomes of less than $10,000 (Piven and Cloward 222).

As the National Voter Registration Act's more popularly-known title suggests, its emphasis is on expanded "moter voter" registration, which casts doubts on how broadly the bill's other major provisions (welfare agency-based and mail registration) will be implemented by state election boards.

Voter registration procedures not addressed by the "motor voter" legislation still vary from state to state (Appendix VII). There are still many structural flaws in these procedures. They include limited hours and locations where registration can occur (CSAE 588), inadequate public education and information campaigns designed to ensure citizens know how and where to go about registering to vote (Piven and Cloward 178), the lack of automatic re-registration for voters who change addresses (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 569), the linkage of jury duty lists to voter registration rolls (Hadley 72), and the continued existence of overly restrictive closing dates for voters to register before elections (Gans 531). Finally, most states do not have fully computerized statewide registration systems (LRC Report Appendix J-5), and underfunded state election boards lack the resources necessary to carry out any proposed reforms.

Antiquated voter registration laws are not the only source of procedural flaws. Obstructionist local election boards in most states also create unnecessary barriers to fuller participation in elections. Local election board officials "are closely connected to local politicians who want the security of a stable and reliable electorate and who therefore resist new and unpredictable voters" (Piven and Cloward 196). Like any bureaucrats, they are hesitant to take on additional work and show resistance to any proposed reforms or changes in their established practices. A dozen or so lawsuits were filed in the 1980s against local election boards who refused to deputize volunteers involved with community voter registration campaigns, in states including Massachusetts, Connecticut, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Indiana, and Michigan (Piven and Cloward 179).

Even today in some counties, voter registration is available only in an extremely limited number of locations, at inconvenient hours. Most election boards do not implement public education campaigns to inform citizens how and where to go about registering to vote.

"There is still only one registration office in many counties, and it might be open only during working hours, thus creating an income test because of travel costs, as well as an education test, since it is not easy to discover the location of many boards of elections. Few boards are willing to establish satellite registration centers in poor neighborhoods...the widely heralded reforms of the registration process during the last fifteen years have had little impact on these barriers. Registration by mail has not raised registration levels because election fficials refuse to make the forms widely available where people live or ork. Arranging to obtain a form is not simple. Even finding the telephone number of an election office in the typical directory can be difficult, since the names by which election boards go are bewildering" (Piven and Cloward 178).

A citizen's voter registration does not automatically follow them when they move. People must re-register whenever they change addresses, creating complications for our highly mobile population. Students who travel away from home to attend college are one group particularly affected. This is an especially troubling development because it discourages citizens from voting immediately after they become eligible to vote.

Court decisions in the 1970s ruled students were entitled to vote where they attend college. Yet in order to do so, students need to either be previously registered in their home towns, and apply for absentee ballots, or register to vote in the communities where they go to school.

The rules governing application for absentee ballots are not well publicized by most county election boards. College towns and universities themselves often take no special steps to ensure their student populations have access to voter registration. Thus, students who want to vote don't know where to turn. College students are structurally discouraged from voting during a crucial period in their development as citizens. True, they represent only a minority of their age groups, since most Americans do not attend college, but this is still one of the reasons younger Americans vote at such low levels.

In most states, citizens are chosen to serve jury duty from the ranks of voter registration rolls. At one point in the 1970s, California's Field poll "uncovered 5 percent of their sample of non-voters in California who were not registered to avoid jury duty" (Hadley 72-73). This figure may be on the low side, since voters who do not register for this reason are understandably reluctant to admit to it.

Finally, there is the dilemma of early voter registration deadlines. In most states, voter registration deadlines fall anywhere from two weeks to four weeks before general elections occur (Appendix VII). All political campaigns intensify in the closing weeks before election day. Indeed, many people only begin to pay serious attention to upcoming elections during the last one or two weeks (Haley 123). In contrast to the fanfare that surrounds an election day, the deadline to register to vote passes quietly. Many people decide to vote only in the weeks immediately before an election. Unless they have previously registered, at this point it is too late (Teixeira 108).

Brief mention should be given to one additional type of structural electoral condition that some voting theorists have identified as contributing to low turnout rates. Elections in the United States are traditionally held on Tuesdays, a work day for most Americans. There is no clear consensus as to whether shifting election days to weekends or making them holidays would actually increase turnout (Teixeira 143), but this type of reform is often proposed (NCR 80).


VII. CONCLUSIONS - PROSPECTS FOR FUTURE REFORM

Now that we have examined these five factors in some detail, I will outline specific policy recommendations designed to reverse the trend of declining citizen participation each contributes to, and offer some general conclusions pertaining to the political feasibility of future reform.

A. Increasing Complexity of Society

B. Disparities In Wealth

Again, these first two factors should be regarded as relatively historically constant and subject to little change through electoral policy reform. The only hope is for these factors to be affected by reforms concerning the next three variables under discussion.

C. Levels Of Civic Education

If levels of civic education are a variable open to the influence of public policy reform, what can be done? Schools and the media must bear a shared mission to better educate Americans about our responsibilities as citizens of a democracy, and keep us well informed on an on-going basis. If people develop habits of citizenship from early ages, they will be more likely to vote on a regular basis.

Towards these ends, schools need to begin by teaching civic education more creatively and effectively. In elementary schools, activities such as mock elections could be introduced on a widespread basis as a way to help children become accustomed to the U.S. political system. Mock elections can be conducted on a classroom or school-wide basis, and if timed to coincide with real world elections provide students with a perfect framework for drawing connections between political concepts learned inside and outside of school. The most promising model for these efforts is a program known as "Kids Voting." First introduced in Arizona in 1988, it reached 675,000 Arizona students statewide by 1990, and is spreading to other states. The program involves students from kindergarten through twelfth grades in the voting process.

"Prior to an election, students learn about the democratic process, how to become an informed voter, and the mechanics of registration and voting. During this period, homework assignments include having discussions with their families about pertinent campaign issues and the relative merits of different issues. On election day students accompany their parents to the polling place and cast simulated votes on the same candidates and ballot initiatives that their parents do. Results of these simulated ballots are not thrown away, but are tabulated and distributed to the press (though they do not count in the real election)" (Teixeira 178).

At the middle school and high school level, more sophisticated, comprehensive civic education efforts need to be developed, preferably on a standardized, national basis in order to achieve the maximum possible impact. A national, revamped civic education program could combine classroom instruction with voter registration made available to all high school seniors, in order to help people develop a habit of voting immediately upon becoming eligible.

Such a program model for high schools has already been developed by People For the American Way, and as of February, 1992 was in the process of implementation in six states, including Florida, Minnesota, Ohio, and North Carolina.

"First Vote was created to assist the educational system in becoming more effective in imparting the skills and knowledge of citizenship... There are three components to the program: a videotaped overview, a six-lesson teaching unit, and on-site voter registration for high school seniors. It was introduced in the Charlotte/Mecklenburg school system in October, 1991, and during its first presentation registered 400 students to vote" (LRC Appendix F-2).

Since early 1992 the North Carolina chapter of People For The American Way has been working with the N.C. League of Women Voters, the N.C. Bar Association and the N.C. Association of Classroom teachers to "develop a collaborative effort for statewide expansion" (LRC Appendix F-2).

Regarding the media, things will only change when corporate control of the U.S. mass media ends. Direct government control is also no answer to this problem. Only a new direction will provide true hope for returning the media to a mission of public service. There must be a third way. It will be difficult, but the media must be wrested away from for-profit, private interests and transformed into non-profit organizations, while remaining independent of government control.

One method would be to focus attention solely on broadcast media and newspapers. First, all existing television stations, cable systems, and big city newspapers could be nationalized. Legislation could be passed designating them non-profit, non-governmental organizations (NGO's). Next, additional legislation would be needed to institutionalize the provision of some levels of government funding to these new media organizations, but independent of government controls over staffing.

Advertising would be allowed to continue at moderate levels, and advertisers would continue to pay for it, (on television, at least, because advertisers need television), providing the media NGO's with additional revenue. The removal of the need to realize profits and the addition of government subsidies would go a long way towards alleviating advertiser influence over programming.

This is, admittedly, a radical scheme. Yet however it happens, the mass media must become a set of institutions dedicated to truly informing the U.S. public if our democracy is to survive.

D. Financing Of Elections

To break the stranglehold wealthy special interests have on our political system, the playing field of electoral competition must be leveled. The only two genuine ways to do this are (1) through the institution of campaign finance reform that includes public campaign financing legislation, and (2) mandating privately owned television stations to provide some amounts of free air time to competing political candidates. With regards to campaign finance reform, initial steps might be to reduce the amount of money PAC's can contribute to candidates from $5,000 in primary and general elections to $1,000 in each, and outlaw the ability of PAC's to act as collection points for the bundling of campaign contributions (Smith 259). Limited public financing of congressional elections should be provided in order to better even the odds between incumbents and challengers.

Washington Post political reporter Paul Taylor has suggested a novel way to legislate the provision of free media time to political candidates on the state and national levels. His proposal, labeled the "five minute fix" (Taylor 267-280), would mandate 5 minutes of broadcast time per night on every radio and television station in the nation be given to major presidential candidates in presidential years; at, say, 7:55 p.m., for the six weeks immediately preceding general elections. Each candidate would appear on alternating nights. The broadcast would air at 7:55 p.m. in each of the country's time zones, the only stipulation being the candidates themselves (or their running mates) have to appear each night, not their surrogates. An additional 5 minutes of air time would be given to state and local candidates, with each state's political parties deciding how to allocate the time. These broadcasts would also air at set times; for example, 7:50 p.m. in presidential years, and 7:55 p.m. in off-years.

Taylor's proposal is an innovative one, and represents a detailed, plausible method by which the allocation of free media time could function. However, it deserves modification. The goal of better informing citizens about issues could better be achieved if two competing voices were heard in each sitting, rather than having two candidates alternate from one night to the next. Ten minutes a night in free air time provided to each of the national and state political parties seems a small price to pay for revitalizing our democracy.

E. Structural Electoral Rules

Too-frequent elections

The first structural bias against broader participation rates is an overly frequent election schedule. How frequent is too frequent? To begin with, the terms for Congress (two years) and the Presidency (four years) are constitutionally mandated, and thus should be regarded as very resistant to change. The system of nominating candidates in partisan primary elections should also be considered fairly well entrenched, although there is still room for reform in some states, mostly Southern, which retain run-off primaries. These are remnants of the years when one-party control and black disfranchisement characterized the South (Piven and Cloward 75-76). One view says these "second primaries" still function to exclude minority candidates from gaining party nominations, while a competing argument is that they help ensure the nomination of only those candidates who can attract the sort of bi-racial or overwhelming white voting-bloc support necessary for political victory in today's South.

An optimal frequency might be if elections for all state and local offices were held only in conjunction with these national election cycles, i.e., once every two years. This would actually mean citizens would vote twice every two years, once to nominate candidates in a primary and again in a general election.

Winner-take-all

The second structural electoral bias to be addressed is the U.S. system of winner-take-all voting. One solution would be to institute a system of legislative proportional representation similar to what exists in Germany or the Netherlands. Single-member House of Representatives and state legislative districts could be abolished and replaced with multimember districts covering entire states or large subdivisions of states (Cossolotto 1991, 1992; and Amy 1992). This sort of system would not affect the U.S. Senate, since "it would be quite difficult, if not impossible, to distribute the two-senator-per-state allocation on other than a winner-take-all basis." (Teixeira 152). However, the electoral college could be replaced with direct presidential election by popular vote.

Critics of proportional representation have long claimed:

"the entry of multiple parties into coalition governments...(under a system of proportional representation) probably depresses turnout...in
countries with high multipartyism, voters are more likely to feel their votes have been diluted by the necessity to compromise with other
parties." (Teixeira 15-16).

The problem with this analysis is it forgets crucial differences between the U.S. and most parliamentary democracies. Here, the national government is controlled by the victorious party in separate presidential elections, not by the party with a congressional majority. This casts doubts on whether a U.S. system of congressional and state legislative proportional representation would decrease turnout.

However, introducing any sort of proportional representation into the U.S. electoral system has always been pronounced politically infeasible, mainly because it would cause "political disruption of unknown magnitude" (Teixeira 154). Furthermore, abolishing the electoral college would require a constitutional amendment.

Yet there is one electoral competition reform that could be instituted at national, state and local levels, used with equal effectiveness for Senate, House, and Presidential elections, but preserve both the electoral college and single-member Congressional and state legislative districts, thus causing a minimum of political disruption. This reform is known as majority preferential voting.

Used in Australia since the 1920s, and in New York City school board elections since the early 1970s (Dillon A10), majority preferential voting does not institute proportional representation. It does ensure voters' choices are more accurately reflected than they would be under a winner-take-all system of voting, while simultaneously guaranteeing winners will have majority support. So how does it work?

As former third-party presidential candidate John Anderson explained in a 1992 New York Times op-ed supporting this reform:

"Rather than simply vote for one candidate, voters rank candidates in order of preference, putting a 1 next to their first choice, a 2 next to
their second choice and so on until they no longer want to support any remaining candidate. After voting is completed, first choices are counted. If a candidate receives more than 50 percent, he or she wins. But if no candidate has a majority, the candidate with fewest first-choice votes is eliminated, and the ballots of voters who indicated that candidate as their first choice are redistributed to their second choices. This process continues until a candidate gains over 50 percent" (J. Anderson A25).

Benefits of preferential voting include cost savings from the abolishment of run-off elections it would facilitate. Run-offs would no longer be necessary to ensure candidates were elected with majority support. This would increase the likelihood of a high voter turnout in the determining election, since in run-offs, supporters of previously eliminated candidates often do not vote. It would also discourage negative campaigning and encourage a focus on issues rather than personal attacks, since candidates would be less likely to want to alienate other candidates' supporters whose second choice votes they may need. As we have seen, the rise of 30-second negative advertising is yet another factor contributing to popular alienation from politics, so this particular side effect of majority preferential voting would be a welcome one. Best of all, this reform would open up the two-party system to multiparty competition without the negative effects on participation (if any) associated with proportional representation.

Voter Registration

Finally, some remedies for the structural bias of personal voter registration requirements. This area represents the best hope for structural reform, partially because voter registration is less structural in nature than first-past-the-post voting or election frequency, and thus less resistant to change. Voter registration legislation is also a narrow area of public policy where the possibility of reform genuinely remains open, as evidenced by recent passage of the 1993 "Moter Voter" Act (Appendix X).

Agency-based voter registration

The provisions of the "Moter Voter" Act are a step in the right direction. Even beyond concerns about the effectiveness of its implementation, however, it will take time for any effects the bill does have to be felt on a national scale. Until then, there will remain a need for agency-based registration to be expanded to more government agencies.

"If people could register in the course of using services as diverse as welfare, Social Security, nutrition, employment, agriculture, education, and day care, the United States would have universalized access to the electoral system" (Piven and Cloward 246).

It is infeasible to propose that voter registration be provided at the counters of every public agency in the country, for reasons of costs and efficiency. Access to registration should exist, however, at several primary governmental agencies. As mandated under the terms of the "Moter Voter" Act, driver's license bureaus, welfare offices, disability agencies, and military recruitment centers are a good start. To this list I would add federal post offices, unemployment agencies, and public libraries, including those located on college campuses. On a regular basis, state and local election boards should be encouraged to conduct voter registration campaigns in other places where large numbers of people congregate, such as shopping malls.

Limited hours and locations where registration can occur

A further expansion of agency-based registration would solve this problem. However, reforms will still have to occur on the local level. The energies of local election boards must be re-directed away from restricting access to the electoral system and towards helping make it more inclusive for all citizens.

Inadequate public education and information campaigns

Federal funding could be made available for aggressive public education campaigns to inform people of the new, wider availability of voter registration. Public service announcements and advertisements would be created and widely disseminated on commercial radio and television. This would ensure that citizens are able to find out how to go about getting registered to vote.

Lack of automatic re-registration for voters who change addresses

This structural barrier could easily be removed if voter re-registration became automatic when people move. Since people almost always file change of address forms at their old post office, it would be a simple matter to carbonize this form and send the second copy to the state elections board.

"The vast majority of moves (83% in 1980-81) are within the same state. For intrastate movers who were registered already, the change of address notice could shift the registration from the old to the new address. If the movers were not registered, a mail registration form could be sent to the new address. If they were headed out of state, a notice could be sent to the state election board in the state of their destination" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 569).

A bill (H.R. 1668) which would do just this was introduced in the House by Rep. Mel Levine (D-CA) in 1985. A similar measure (S. 1439) was offered in the Senate by Sen. Chris Dodd (D-CT) and Sen. John Chafee (R-R.I.). Its fate was unremarkable - "H.R. 1668 was unanimously reported by the Subcommittee on Postal Operations and Services in July 1985 and died in its parent Committee on Post Office and Civil Service" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 572).

In the absence of such a nationwide remedy, college towns and universities could start living up to their responsibilities to take the needs of their student residents into account. Campus access to voter registration could be institutionalized, and other steps taken to create an atmosphere conducive to local political involvement by students. Universities and college towns are ideal environments to help spark creation of a renewed culture of political participation.

Linkage of jury duty lists to voter registration rolls

Despite its negative effects on voter registration rates, the linkage between jury duty lists and voter registration rolls has usually been justified on grounds of it being perfectly reasonable to ask citizens to perform an infrequent, limited civic duty such as serving jury duty in exchange for the privilege of voting (Hadley 72).

However, this argument ignores the fact that it is generally more difficult for lower income Americans to be granted time off from their jobs for jury duty, or for them to afford being able to do so. The situation is further complicated since the electorate is currently skewed more heavily towards upper class than lower class Americans (Piven and Cloward 4), and therefore, lower class underrepresentation on juries may also be a factor behind the U.S. legal system's bias against lower class defendants (Zinn 505-507).

The most obvious solution to this dilemma is to link jury duty lists to some other form of citizen rosters, such as driver's license records. In order to counter the upward class bias also inherent in these records, welfare rolls and unemployment benefit rolls could also be utilized. If we are serious about wanting to increase levels of citizen participation, we shouldn't be actively providing people with reasons not to vote.

Underfunded state election boards / Lack of fully computerized statewide registration systems

Federal funding could be channeled into an expansion and overhaul of state election boards. This would allow for the modernization of state election boards' computer systems and enable them to process registrations from the expanded networks of statewide registration sites. In addition to keeping track of within-state registration transfers, computerization would also facilitate more accurate efforts to keep registration rolls updated (i.e., free of voters who have moved out of state or died since last registering), since the "Moter Voter" Act has now outlawed purging citizens simply for not voting. This in turn would allow election boards to keep more accurate records regarding the true levels of voter registration in their jurisdictions and better focus any efforts designed to raise these rates.

Election day holidays

There is no clear consensus as to whether shifting election days to weekends or making them holidays would actually increase turnout (Teixeira 143). Evidence from states and municipalities that have experimented with such practices such as Cleveland, Ohio, Milwaukee County, Wisconsin, Texas, and Louisiana, suggests that turnout may actually decrease (NCR 80), perhaps because people are likely to want to take advantage of a rare day off from work! The most convincing argument against this type of reform is based on the high turnout rates of registered Americans (Appendix V), which shows that once people are registered, they tend to vote.

Election day holidays are designed to "improve the turnout of people who are already very likely to vote" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 569), instead of reaching out to those Americans who are not registered.

However, it would make sense to uniformly lengthen polling hour closings on election days to 9:00 pm or 10:00 pm. Working Americans should be able to vote after work without having to stand in line for several hours, or miss voting because they couldn't get to the polls before 7:00 pm. A related reform involves systems of so-called early voting, introduced in Texas in 1991 and increasingly being implemented in other areas of the country. Early voting in Texas allows citizens to vote for 17 days prior to elections at special polling places in grocery stores, shopping malls and other public places instead of at their polling places on election day. So far, it has increased turnout in Texas slightly (Cooper and Christe 5).

Overly restrictive registration closing dates

In the past, thirty-day closing dates have been justified on the grounds that election workers need that much time to prepare accurate, updated precinct lists of all registered voters by election day. With the growing use of computers and high-speed database technology, these arguments are no longer as valid.

Voter registration deadlines in all fifty states could be set at one week before general elections. This would increase the registration time period for everyone, and ensure the participation of more citizens who decide to vote only in the weeks immediately before an election (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 568).

The logical extension of shortening registration closing dates is to allow election day registration (Gans 531). Four states currently do so: Minnesota, Wisconsin, Maine, and North Dakota, which has no voter registration (Appendix VII). A fifth, Oregon, experimented with the practice but discontinued it in the mid-1980's.

Voter turnouts in these four states are continually higher than in the U.S. as a whole (Appendix VIII). However, nationwide implementation of this reform should be considered politically infeasible for a number of reasons.

The most important is that such a measure might create opportunities for serious election fraud. Critics have pointed out that the absence of scandals to date in the four states with election day registration can be attributed in part to the "clean political culture" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 568) that exists in these states, and other characteristics they share. "Election day registration has been adopted by four states with (already) relative high levels of voter turnout, relatively homogeneous populations, and low historical levels of voter fraud" (CSAE 595). Republicans were nearly able to block passage of the "Moter Voter" Act by raising fears about the levels of fraud its modest measures would create (McNeely 21A).

Opposition to any national election day registration legislation would certainly be more unyielding and find wider popular support, as it did the last time such legislation was proposed, by President Carter in 1977 (Teixeira 127). In order for any structural electoral reform to successfully increase participation rates, it must give people more, not less, faith in their ability to make a difference by voting. Reforms that might undermine further public confidence in the system by raising the specter of stolen elections would be vastly counterproductive.

Automatic voter registration along the lines of the European model is another possible answer. Yet this too should be seen as a solution "strongly against the grain of American political culture" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 568). Whether implemented through government canvass, as done in Great Britain or Canada, or by adoption of a national voter I.D. card, it would undoubtedly face opposition on grounds that such a measure would violate civil liberties and privacy concerns.

Efforts to use social security numbers or census collection data for any purposes other than the narrow ones for which they were intended have always met with intense public opposition. During debate over immigration reform in the mid-1980s, Rep. Norman Y. Mineta (D-CA) summed up the political realities stacked against this type of measure when he commented that "I do not think that we should travel down the road that could lead toward national identification cards, not one foot, not one inch" (Wolfinger, Glass and Squire 572).

Another feature of some European voting systems that would not work well in America is the existence of compulsory voting laws. Americans' strong sense of individualism and dislike for overly intrusive government actions make this proposal politically infeasible. Again, the implementation of such laws in an attempt to increase citizen participation levels would be counterproductive. In order for participation to be meaningful, it cannot be forced. Americans should be free to choose not to vote, but the point of any voter registration reforms should be to ensure they are not being structurally encouraged to do so.

Projected Impact of Voter Registration Reforms

The effects on voter turnout of reforms involving increased civic education, public campaign financing laws, and most structural electoral changes would be difficult to quantify. This is primarily because little data exists for analysis.

For example, in Arizona, supporters of the "Kids Voting" program claim it increased participation in the 1990 off-year elections by 4%, which was the amount turnout increased that year compared with 1986. But there was also a controversial referendum (on the Martin Luther King holiday) on Arizona ballots that year, (Teixeira 179), and the program has been in existence for too limited a time to specify how much it contributed to the higher turnout. It has been broadly estimated that America's non-competitive electoral system (lack of third-party mobilization, winner-take-all voting) depresses turnout by 20% relative to other major democracies (Teixeira 23).

However, enough individual states have implemented various voter registration reforms over the past two decades to provide data for more detailed analysis of their effectiveness (Appendix VIII). Estimates of the increased turnout resulting from nationwide registration reform range from 7.6% (Wolfinger and Rosenstone 73), to 9.1% (Mitchell and Wlezien 13), to 14% (Powell 77). Despite its political infeasibility, most studies agree this option has the greatest potential to increase turnout. Some think it would likely account for 2/3 of any turnout boost due to voter registration reform (Appendix VIII).

Increasing the number of volunteer registrars in a state is estimated to raise turnout by 2.4% after four years, and 5.0% after eight (CSAE 598). "Motor voter" programs by themselves also increase turnout by some. They also have greater impact over time, increasing turnout by an estimated 1.0% after four years to 3.3% after eight (Appendix VIII). Michigan was the first state to implement "moter-voter" legislation, in 1975. In 1984 alone, drivers license bureaus recorded 266,273 new registrations and 505,888 address changes (Piven and Cloward 220). In 1988, 87.7% of Michigan's voting age population was registered to vote. That same year, presidential turnout in Michigan was 54%, compared with 50.2% nationally (LRC Report Appendix E-3).

Costs of Proposed Reforms

I have not focused extensively on the issue of costs in this paper because little quantitative data exists concerning the broader structural reforms I am advocating. But this is not true of voter registration reform. Registration reforms have been almost universally recognized as extremely cost efficient. The 1993 "Moter Voter" Act is expected to cost the states $200 million, but this figure mostly reflects the amount all would need to spend to fully computerize their registration systems (Ross 1). Other reforms outlined here would cost much less to implement.

Agency-based registration is one of the least expensive reform options. Michigan's "moter voter" program has estimated its costs at $0.17 per new voter. "There is no reason why costs should be greater in unemployment or welfare agencies...at these rates, a state could register 500,000 people at a cost of less than $100,000" (Piven and Cloward 220, 234). Other measures are calculated to be similarly inexpensive. The N.C. Secretary of State's office estimated its annual needs for increased state funding of voting information and voter education programs (for a state voting-age population of just over five million) at $50,000 (LRC Report Appendix J-15), or just $.01 a voter! A 1992 proposal for election-day registration in North Carolina was projected to cost the state only $14,000 - the amount needed to hire two additional election workers to staff a central registration site in each county, paid $5 an hour for working a 14 hour day (LRC Report Appendix K-3). The average annual costs spent by North Carolina's state elections board to administer its "moter-voter" program are $3,500 spent printing forms and $7,200 in postage, a total of $10,700. (LRC Report Appendix I-5).

With costs as low as this, there is no reason not to move ahead with reforms that go as far as possible towards removing the barriers to fuller participation created by our country's system of personal voter registration equirements. By making it easier for people to register to vote, turnout figures can be increased (Appendix V, IX). True, only 104 million of the 190 million Americans eligible to vote did so in the 1992 presidential election. But only 2/3 of them (127 million) were even registered to vote. Viewed in this light, 1992 turnout of registered voters was 82%, a turnout level comparable to those in other industrialized democracies (Appendix IX).

Final Thoughts

The reforms I have outlined in this paper touch many areas of our society. If steps are taken towards implementing any of them - the provision of more focused civic education and objective information in schools and on television, enactment of public campaign financing laws, and structural electoral reform (less frequent election scheduling, the adoption of majority preferential voting, and liberalized voter registration procedures) - voter turnout and citizen participation will increase.

A more informed and active public will be better able to counter the influence special interests now exert on matters of public policy. Over time, this will lead to the election of lawmakers dedicated to represent the public interest before private interests.

We are supposedly a democracy, yet time and time again, decisions are made that only serve elite interests. Companies downsize and move their production lines overseas, enforcing continued Third World poverty while lowering living standards for U.S. workers. Education and social service budgets are slashed, but we continue to spend upwards of $260 billion a year on weapons of destruction. Only the wealthy or those who serve the interests of the wealthy can afford to run for office, so we're governed by an entire class of elected officials who aren't representing most Americans.

Returning to an earlier theme, today many people are confused. They look around them and see a nation and world spinning out of control, with mounting social problems and signs of moral, physical, and societal decay evident everywhere. To pierce this collective veil of confusion, we must honestly assess what events have brought us to this point and why. It is in this spirit that I have sought to draw attention to the factors hard at work creating mass political alienation and undermining American participatory democracy in the process.


BIBLIOGRAPHY / WORKS CITED

--- , "The 1992 Campaign: Helms Campaign Signs Decree On Racial Postcards," New York Times, February 28, 1992, p A18.

--- , "Campaign Ads: 35% In Senate Campaign Budgets, 25% In House," The Hotline, March 19, 1991.

--- , "Illiterate Americans," New York Times, September 14, 1993, editorial, p A 24.

--- , "Lifestyles of the Rich and Fatuous," Extra!Update (The Bi-Monthly Newsletter of FAIR), April 1994, pp 1-4.

--- , "Register To Vote in 1984," National Civic Review, February 1984, editorial, pp 51-52.

--- , "U.S. Settles North Carolina Vote Charge," Washington Post, February 27, 1992, p A3.

--- , "Will More People Vote On Sunday?," National Civic Review, February 1984, pp 80-81.

American Bar Association, The Disappearance of the American Voter Re-Visited: A Symposium on Declining Voter Participation, November 10-11, 1989. Austin, TX: American Bar Association, 1990.

Amy, Douglas J. "Real Elections: The Case For Proportional Representation in the U.S." Department of Politics, Mount Holyoke College, 1992.

John B. Anderson, "Break The Political Stranglehold," New York Times, July 24, 1992, p A25.

Harry Anderson, "Fuming Over College Costs," Newsweek, May 18, 1987, pp 66-71.

Arrington, Theodore S. and Timothy D. Mead, "Outreach Programs and Voter Registration in North Carolina," State and Local Government Review, vol. 24, Fall 1992, pp 113-116.

Robert Atwan, "Let's Look At This Illiteracy Study," New York Times, September 20, 1993, letter, p A18.

Bagdikian, Ben H. The Media Monopoly, 3rd ed. Boston: Beacon Press, 1990.

Jeremy Brecher, "After NAFTA: Global Village or Global Pillage?," The Nation, vol. 257, no. 19, December 6, 1993, pp 685-688.

Brown, Lester R. The Twenty-Ninth Day. New York: Norton, 1978.

Walter Dean Burnham, "The Appearance and the Disappearance of the American Voter," in The Disappearance of the American Voter. Washington, D.C.: American Bar Association, 1979.

William Celis 3d, "Study Says Half of Adults in U.S. Lack Reading and Math Abilities," New York Times, September 9, 1993, p A1.

Noam Chomsky, "Notes On NAFTA: The Masters of Mankind," The Nation, vol. 256, no. 12, March 29, 1993, pp 412-416.

Cirino, Robert. Don't Blame The People: How The News Media Use Bias, Distortion and Censorship To Manipulate Public Opinion. Los Angeles, CA: Diversity Press, 1971.

Adam Clymer, "Turnout on Election Day '92 Was the Largest in 24 Years," New York Times, December 17, 1992, p A9.

Committee for the Study of the American Electorate, "Creating the Opportunity: Voting and the Crisis of Democracy," Policy Studies Review, vol. 9, no. 3, Spring 1990, pp 583-601.

Cooper, Jamie and Ian Christe. Policy Alternatives on Voter Participation: A State Report, vol. 3. Washington, D.C.: Center for Policy Alternatives, December 1991.

Matthew Cossolotto, "A Competitive Politics," Christian Science Monitor, November 21, 1991.

Matthew Cossolotto, "The Representation Deficit." Alexandria, VA: Citizens for Proportional Representation, 1992.

Crawford, Alan. Thunder On The Right: The "New Right" and the Politics of Resentment. New York: Pantheon Books, 1980.

William Crotty, "Setting Forth Premises: The Politically Invisible," Policy Studies Review, vol. 9, no. 3, Spring 1990, pp 505-515.

Steve Daley, "TV Holds Power In Politics: 'Tool of Enlightenment Dims Amid Hard Campaigns," Chicago Tribune, zone C, p 1.

Davis, David Howard. Energy Politics, 4th ed. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1993.

Jay F. Davis, "From Awareness To Action: Media Literacy For The 90's," pamphlet, Los Angeles: Center For Media and Values, 1990, pp 1-8.

Jason DePerle, "Sharp Increase Along The Borders of Poverty," New York Times, March 31, 1994, p A10.

Sam Dillon, "New York School Fight Shifts To Elections For Local Boards, New York Times, February 17, 1993, p A1.

Dionne, E.J. Jr. Why Americans Hate Politics. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1991.

Domhoff, William G. Who Rules America Now?: A View For The '80's. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1983.

Dominick, J.R. The Dynamics of Mass Communication. New York: McGraw Hill, 1990.

Edds, Margaret. Free At Last: What Really Happened When Civil Rights Came To Southern Politics. Bethesda, MD: Adler and Adler, 1987.

Thomas B. Edsall, "Bush Takes No Stand On Ballot Plan; Program Targeted N.C. Black Voters," Washington Post, November 9, 1990, p A13.

Duane Elgin, "TV Plus Telephone Equals Electronic Democracy," Utne Reader, July/August 1990, pp 70-71.

Philip Elmer-Dewitt, "Take a Trip Into the Future on the Electronic Superhighway," Time, April 12, 1993, pp 50-58.

Findley, Paul. Deliberate Deceptions: Facing The Facts about the U.S.-Israeli Relationship. Brooklyn, N.Y.: Lawrence Hill Books, 1993.

Fish, Joe and Cristina Sganga. El Salvador: Testament of Terror. London: Zed Books, 1988.

Joe Flint, "Political Advertising: Good news/Bad news; It's Still a Bonanza For Broadcasters But a Pain in the Neck As Well; Gross May Reach $300 Million by Nov. 6," Broadcasting, vol. 119, no. 18, October 29, 1990, p 27.

Sarah Fritz and Dwight Morris, "Burden Of TV Election Ads Exaggerated, Study Finds," Los Angeles Times, March 18, 1991, Part A, p 1.

Curtis B. Gans, "Remobilizing The American Electorate," Policy Studies Review, vol. 9, no. 3, Spring 1990, pp 527-538.

Gilmour, Robert S. and Robert S. Lamb, Political Alienation in Contemporary America.

Cathy Lynn Grossman, "Shrinking Piece of the Pie May Be Good Cause To Whine," USA Today, April 26, 1994, p 3D.

Hadley, Arthur T. The Empty Polling Booth. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1979.

Harrington, Michael. The New American Poverty. New York: Penguin Books, 1984.

Bob Herbert, "In America: On Spelling Kat," New York Times, September 12, 1993, sec. 4, p 19.

Hofstadter, Richard. Anti-Intellectualism In American Life. New York: Vintage Books, 1962.

Jamieson, Kathleen Hall. Dirty Politics: Deception, Distraction, and Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1992.

Vicki Kemper, "Voter Turn-Off," Common Cause Magazine, April/May/June 1992.

Kousser, J. Morgan. The Shaping of Southern Politics: Suffrage Restrictions and the Establishment of the One-Party South. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1974.

LaFeber, Walter. Inevitable Revolutions: The United States in Central America, 2nd ed. New York: W.W. Norton and Company, 1993.

Lee, M.A. and Norman Solomon. Unreliable Sources: A Guide To Detecting Bias in News Media. New York: Carol Publishing Group, 1991.

Legislative Research Commission, Voter Participation: Report to the 1991 General Assembly of North Carolina 1992 Session. Raleigh, N.C.: State of North Carolina, 1992.

Leuchtenburg, William E. A Troubled Feast: American Society Since 1945, updated ed. Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1983.

Dave McNeely, "Expanding The Right To Vote," Dallas Morning News, May 21, 1993, p A21.

Mitchell, Glen and Christopher Wlezien, "Voter Registration Laws and Turnout 1972-1982," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, 1989.

William C. Mitchell, "Ambiguity, Contradictions, and Frustrations at the Ballot Box: A Public Choice Perspective," Policy Studies Review, vol. 9, no. 3, Spring 1990, pp 517-525.

National Municipal League Election Systems Project, "A Model Voter Registration System," National Civic Review, March 1984, pp 104-117.

Noble, David F. America By Design: Science, Technology, and the Rise of Corporate Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1977.

Parenti, Michael. Inventing Reality: The Politics of News Media. New York: St. Martin's Press.

John Pilger, "Journey To East Timor: Land of the Dead," The Nation, vol. 258, no. 16, April 25, 1994, pp 550-552.

Piven, Frances Fox and Richard A. Cloward. Why Americans Don't Vote. New York: Pantheon Books, 1988.

Elaine S. Povich, "In Congress, Money Talks - And Re-Elects," Chicago Tribune, November 20, 1990, Zone C, p 1.

G. Bingham Powell, Jr. "American Voter Turnout in Comparative Perspective," American Political Science Review, vol 80., pp 17-44.

Chuck Raasch, "Poll: Most Americans Too Cynical, Busy For Politics," Gannett News Service, June 13, 1993, p 1.

Michael Ross, "Landmark Voter Bill OK'd; GOP Filibuster Fails," Los Angeles Times, May 12, 1993, Part A, p 1.

Jerry Seper, "Justice Dept. Says Helms Intimidated Black Voters," Washington Times, February 27, 1992, p A3.

Schwartz, David C. Political Alienation and Political Behavior. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 1973.

Slater, Philip E. The Pursuit Of Loneliness: American Culture At Its Breaking Point. Boston: Beacon Press, 1970.

Smith, Hedrick. The Power Game: How Washington Works. New York: Ballantine Books, 1988.

Brent Staples, "Dirty Political Ads, Reconsidered," New York Times, November 11, 1990, sec. 4, p 16.

Donald Stewart, "U.S. College Tuition Rose 12 Percent," Durham Herald Sun, October 16, 1991, p A5.

Katherine Tate, "Black Political Participation in the 1984 and 1988 Presidential Elections," American Political Science Review, vol. 85, no. 4, December 1991, pp 1159-1176.

Taylor, Paul. See How They Run: Electing The President In An Age Of Mediaocracy. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1990.

Teixeira, Ruy A. The Disappearing American Voter. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1992.

Joseph Ungaro, "First The Bad News," Media Studies Journal, vol. 5, no. 4, pp 101-113.

Weiss, Michael J. The Clustering of America. New York: Harper and Row, 1988.

Wolfinger, Raymond E. and Steven J. Rosenstone, Who Votes?. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1980.

Wolfinger, Raymond E., David P. Glass, and Peverill Squire, "Predictors of International Turnout: An International Comparison," Policy Studies Review, vol. 9, no. 3, Spring 1990, pp 551-574.

Zinn, Howard. A People's History of the United States. New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1980.

Rogues Gallery

All Posts by Category

Tags

#ChapelHillShooting #MuslimLivesMatter (1) $400 haircuts (3) 1960s (1) 1980s (1) 1984 (1) 1988 elections (1) 1989 (1) 1990 elections (3) 1992 elections (1) 1993 (3) 1994 elections (1) 1996 elections (3) 1998 elections (1) 2000 elections (3) 2004 (7) 2004 elections (2) 2008 (32) 2008 congressional races (2) 2012 elections (3) 2014 elections (13) 2016 elections (7) 527 groups (1) 9/11 (4) 9/11 first anniversary (1) Abba Eban (1) Abbe Raven (1) Abbie Hoffman (2) ABC (1) abortion (3) action alert (7) activism (2) advertising (2) advocacy (1) affair (4) Affordable Care Act (1) affordable housing fund (1) afghanistan (2) Age of Obama (1) AIDS (1) AIDS victims (2) AIPAC (1) al gore (2) Al Sharpton (1) Alec Guettal (3) alienation (2) Alison Lundergan Grimes (1) alternative energy (10) Alzheimer's (1) amanda marcotte (2) American Left (4) Americans for Limited Government (1) Americans For Prosperity (1) Amnon Rubenstein (1) andrew young (3) Angelo Robinson (1) anti-communism (1) anti-gay bigotry (1) anti-gay violence (1) anti-immigration activists (2) anti-science (1) anti-Semitism (1) anti-vaccine (1) anti-vaxxers (1) anti-war (6) appeal to southern voters (1) apprentice (1) Ariel Sharon (1) Ashley Todd (2) assassinations (2) Astroturf (1) atheism (1) attack ads (5) attack on voter rights (4) Australia (1) autism (1) average Americans (1) baby boomers (1) baby formula (1) bank of america (1) bankruptcy reform (1) barack obama (24) Barry Commoner (2) BBC (1) Benghazi (1) Benjamin L. Ginsberg (1) Bensonhurst (1) Berkeley (1) Beth Ising (2) bi-racial coalition (1) Biden-Palin Debate (1) big banks (1) big money (4) bigotry (7) bill clinton (6) bill donohue (1) Bill Hedrick (1) Bill O'Reilly (1) billionaires (1) Billy Bragg (1) Black Cultural Center (1) Black Lives Matter (4) black voters (7) Blan Holman (1) block the vote (1) bloggergate (1) bloggers (1) blogosphere (1) Bob Dole (1) Bob Iger (1) bob johnson (1) body cameras (1) books (3) Borders (2) BP (2) Brad Blog (1) Brad Friedman (1) Bruce Braley (4) budget deficit (1) bush (7) Bush Administration (2) bush administration misconduct (3) bush donor (1) bush on steroids (1) bush v. gore (1) California (1) Camilo Padreda (1) campaign feud (1) campaign finance reform (8) campaign gaffes (2) campaign scandals (4) campaigns (1) can edwards win (3) canvassing (1) capitalism (2) Catalyst (5) censorship (5) Cesar Chavez (1) Chad Taylor (1) Channel One (1) chapel hill (7) chapel hill town council (3) Charlie Black (1) Charlie Crist (1) Chatham County (1) chemical industry (2) children (1) chris hughes (1) Chris Whittle (1) Christine O'Donnell (1) CIA (3) CIA recruiting (1) CIA torture report (1) citizen participation (1) Citizens United (1) civil disobedience (2) civil rights (7) civil rights movement (1) civilian casualties (2) Civitas Institute (1) class issues (1) Clean Up Congress (1) Clear Channel (2) Clinton Administration (3) code words (1) Cold War (1) colin powell (1) Colin Small (1) college campuses (2) colonialism (1) columbia (1) community reinvestment (1) community reinvestment act (1) concentration of mass media ownership (4) Concord (1) congress (7) conservation (1) consumer fraud (2) consumers (2) Coors (1) corporate accountability (8) corporate front groups (1) corporate giveaways (2) corporate greed (1) corporate influence (4) corporate media (2) corporate misconduct (8) corporations (8) corruption (1) counter-inaugural (1) CRA (1) cra-nc (2) Craig Hicks (1) CRomnibus (2) crony capitalism (1) cross burnings (1) Crossroads GPS (1) Cuba (1) cuban exiles (1) cultural imperialism (1) Dale McKinley (1) damage control (2) Dana Rohrabacher (1) dark money (3) Darren Wilson (2) David Ball (2) David Brower (1) David Dellinger (1) David Duke (1) David Horowitz (1) Deah Barakat (1) debates (1) Debbie Cook (1) demagogues (3) democracy (6) Democratic Convention (1) democratic nomination (15) democratic party (2) Democrats (2) Denis Hayes (1) deregulation (1) detainees (1) Dick Cheney (1) dictatorships (1) dirty tricks (4) discrimination (1) Disney (1) disparate treatment (1) diversity (1) divisive politics (3) Dominican Republic (1) Donald Rumsfeld (1) donald trump (4) dumpstering (2) durham (2) e-mail (2) early voting (2) Ebola (2) economic inequality (2) economic issues (1) economy (4) ed meese (1) Ed Rollins (1) Edison Project (1) edith childs (1) education (2) edwards affair (4) election day 2008 (1) election fraud (1) electoral college (1) Eliot Spitzer (1) Elizabeth Dole (1) elizabeth edwards (2) Elizabeth Warren (3) Emily Lawson (1) employee pensions (1) end racism (4) energy independence (9) entertaining ourselves to death (5) environment (15) environmental pollution (5) environmental racism (2) Eric Garner (2) Eric Holder (1) Eric Odell (2) Ericka Kurz (21) evan bayh (1) Executive Orders (1) expenditures (1) exploitation of 9/11 (2) Exxon Valdez (1) factory farming (1) Faux News (1) FBI (1) Fear (1) fec (1) feminism (1) Ferguson (3) Fidel Castro (2) field plan (1) financial house of cards (1) fire (1) Fire From The Mountain (1) firebombing (2) fired up (1) first openly gay elected official in south (1) Florida (1) florida recount (1) foreign policy (1) Fox News (1) fraud (1) fraudulent inauguration (2) Frederick Douglass (1) Free Speech Movement (1) freedom songs (1) friend (1) fuel efficiency (1) fundraising (2) gary hart (1) gay (6) gay history (2) gay marriage (1) gay-baiting (4) Gaza (2) gen. david petraeus (1) gender equality (1) general election (23) Generation X (1) George H.W. Bush (9) George Norris (1) george w. bush (12) Geraldine Ferraro (1) Germany (2) gerrymandering (1) get-out-the-vote (3) GLBT community (1) global warming (2) GOP (27) GOP Slime Machine (10) GOTV (3) government harassment (1) government secrecy (1) great recession (1) greed (1) Greg Orman (1) grocery store (1) ground game (1) ground zero (1) GSE's (1) guerrillas (1) guest workers (1) Gulf War (5) gun violence (1) h+r block (1) hackers (2) Hamas (2) Harriet Ann Jacobs (2) Harris Wofford (1) Harry Blackmun (1) Harry Truman (1) Harvey Gantt (6) hate crimes (1) hate-mongering (3) hatred (3) health care reform (4) hedge funds (2) Helen Caldicott (2) Henry Hyde (1) Henry Kissinger (1) Henry Louis Gates Jr. (1) hero (1) Hezbollah (1) hillary clinton (14) historical amnesia (1) history (1) hit the road jack (1) HMO's (1) Ho Chi Minh (1) hoaxes (1) Holocaust (1) home foreclosures (1) homophobia (1) housing (1) Howard Rich (1) HR 1461 (1) Huks (1) Human Rights Campaign (1) hurting communities (1) i feel pretty (1) iit’s a wonderful life (1) immigration (4) immigration action (1) immigration reform (3) Inauguration Day 2009 (1) Incidents In The Life of a Slave Girl (2) income inequality (1) Indigo Girls (1) industrial agriculture (1) industrial revolution (1) integration (1) intelligence community (1) international relations (1) Invasion of Panama (1) Iowa (4) iowa caucuses (1) Ira Magaziner (1) Iran/Contra scandal (1) iraq (2) iraq war (4) iraq war costs (2) Irgun (1) ISIS (1) Islamic State (1) Islamophobia (1) Israel (5) Israeli Labor Party (1) Israeli-Palestinian conflict (6) James Bay II (1) James Carville (1) james watt (1) January 20 2001 (2) January 20 2009 (1) jeb bush (3) Jenn Karson (1) Jenny McCarthy (1) Jeremiah Wright (1) Jerry Falwell (1) Jerry Rubin (1) Jesse Helms (13) jesse jackson (3) Jessecrats (1) Jesus de Galindez (1) JFK Assassination (1) Jill Biden (1) Jim DeMint (1) Jim Hunt (3) Jimmy Langman (3) job losses (3) joe biden (3) joe herzenberg (3) Joe Sestak (1) joe trippi (1) John Boehner (3) john edwards (12) john kerry (4) John Lennon (1) John Locke (1) John McCain (16) John Moody (1) john poindexter (1) John Raese (1) John Reich (1) John Sinclair (1) Joni Ernst (5) June 24 1973 (1) justice (2) justice for all (1) Justice for Mike Brown (1) Kansas (2) Karl Marx (1) Karl Rove (5) Kay Hagan (4) Kayla Mueller (1) Ken Calvert (1) Kentucky (1) Kirti Shastri (1) KKK (1) Koch brothers (4) Korean War (1) Ku Klux Klan (2) labor unions (2) Lakota Woman (1) Lamar Alexander (1) Larry Kissell (1) Latin America (2) Latinos (2) Lawton Chiles (1) lazy journalism (1) Lebanon (1) lee c. wilson (1) legal system (1) Lehman Brothers (1) lesbian (1) liberation theology (1) Libya (1) Likud (3) Linda Brent (2) Lisa Abbott (3) lobbying (1) Louisiana (1) love child scandal (2) lynching (1) macaca moment (1) MAJIC (1) Mandy Carter (1) Marco Rubio (1) Mark Chilton (2) Mark Kleinschmidt (1) Mark Penn (1) marketing (2) Martin Frost (1) Martin Luther King Jr. (1) Mary Brave Bird (1) Mary Crow Dog (1) maternity leave (1) Matt Czajkowski (1) max cleland (1) mayor of franklin street (1) mbna (1) McCain missteps (2) McCain VP (7) McCarthyism (1) McDesperate (4) measles (1) media (2) media bias (3) media failed to inform (2) media hysteria (1) media monopolies (3) medical insurance industry (3) Medicare (1) melissa mcewan (1) memorial (1) Menachem Begin (2) mentor (1) merger (1) Michael Bell (1) Michael Brown (3) Michael Stipe (1) Michele Bachmann (1) Michelle Bachmann (1) michelle malkin (1) Michigan (1) middle east (1) Miguel Recarey (1) Mike Castle (1) Mike Easley (2) Mike Hummell (1) military-industrial complex (3) Millennials (1) Milton Wolf (1) minimum wage (1) mission not accomplished (1) Mitch McConnell (3) Mitt Romney (6) Mobil (2) molly ivins (1) money (1) Moral Majority (3) MOVE (4) multiculturalism (1) multinational corporations (2) Muslim Americans (1) mybo (1) NAACP (1) Nat Turner (1) Nathan Sproul (1) Native Americans (2) nc (4) NC Legislature (1) NC MOBE 96 (1) NC PDP (1) neo-nazis (1) Nestle (1) netroots (3) New Left (1) New Orleans (1) New World Order (1) New York City (3) Nicaragua (2) no justice no peace (1) No More Bushes (1) nobama democrats (1) non-profits (2) North Carolina (23) North Korea (1) nuclear industry (3) Obama Inauguration (1) Obamacare (1) Obsession DVD (1) OCAW (1) occupied territories (2) October 28 2007 (1) offshore drilling (1) Ohio (1) oil (10) oil industry (6) oliver north (1) Omar Cabezas (1) online organizing (1) oppression (2) oprah (1) organizing (12) Orlando Bosch (1) Osama Bin Laden (1) ots (2) outrage (1) overconsumption (1) Palestine (1) pandagon (1) pat buchanan (1) Pat Roberts (2) Pat Toomey (1) patriarchy (2) Paul Wellstone (1) payday lending (1) peace (4) peace is patriotic (1) Peggy Young (1) Pennsylvania (2) Penny Rich (1) Peter King (1) petition (2) pharmaceutical industry (1) Phillipines (1) phonebanking (1) phony billionaire (1) picketing (1) PIRGs (1) PLO (2) police accountability (4) police brutality (5) police oversight (4) political committees (1) political consultants (1) political heroes (1) polls (1) pottersville (1) President Obama (4) presidential campaign (30) privatization of education (2) pro-war propaganda (1) profits (1) progressive Democrats (3) progressives (1) property (1) protest (2) protests (6) Public Citizen (1) public health (2) public opinion (2) publishing industry (2) pulp (1) pulping (2) PUMA (1) race card (1) race relations (5) race riots (2) racism (22) racist terrorism (1) radicals (2) Rafael Trujillo (1) rally (1) ralph nader (3) RALs (1) Rand Paul (2) ray charles (1) reading list (3) reagan's racism (1) recall elections (1) recession of 1991-92 (2) recession of 2008 (1) redbaiting (1) redistricting (1) refugee camps (1) refund anticipation loans (1) reproductive rights (1) Republican National Convention (2) republican party (2) Republican Study Committee (1) returns (2) revolution (1) rich donors (2) Richard Fink (1) Rick Santorum (1) Rick Scott (1) rielle hunter (2) Right Wing (11) right wing Republicans (11) RIP (3) rip-off (1) Robert McCulloch (1) Robert Mercer (1) Robert Redford (2) Robin Hayes (1) ronald reagan (2) Ruby Sinreich (1) rudy giuliani (1) ruling class (1) rush limbaugh (3) Sabra and Shatilla Massacres (1) Sam Brownback (2) same-sex marriage (1) Sandinistas (1) Sarah Palin (14) SAU (1) savings and loans (1) Scamdal (1) schools (1) Scientology (1) Scott Brown (1) SDS (2) SEAC (20) selected not elected (1) Senate races (10) sept. 11 (4) sept. 11 2002 (2) sexism (2) Sharron Angle (1) Sheldon Adelson (1) Shimon Peres (1) single payer health system (2) Six-Day War (1) slaveholders (1) slavery (2) Smithfield Foods (1) social movements (1) social networking (1) solar panels (1) soul music (1) south carolina primary (4) Soviet Union (1) spat (1) Sprint (1) Stand With Peggy (1) state governments (1) Steve Scalise (1) Steve Schmidt (3) stolen election (5) stop bush (1) StopBrownback (1) strange incidents (2) street theatre (1) Student Action Union (1) student activism (19) student voting (3) students (11) subprime lending (1) super PACs (2) superdelegate petition (2) superdelegates (2) supreme court (5) susan baylies (1) swine flu panic (1) Syria (1) take action (16) tax code fairness (2) Tea Party (8) Ted Cruz (3) terrorism (2) Terry Sanford (1) The Revolt (1) The Zionist Dream Revisited (1) these guys (1) third world (3) Thom Tillis (3) Thomas Frank (1) Threshold (8) tim kaine (1) Time Warner (1) tobacco industry (1) Tom DeLay (1) Tongass National Forest (1) Tony Coelho (1) Tony Mazzocchi (1) torture (1) Troopergate (1) trump was born wealthy (1) U.S. power structure (2) UNC-Chapel Hill (5) undocumented immigrants (2) unemployment (1) United Kingdom (2) universal healthcare coverage (6) unprovoked war (1) UpStairs Lounge (1) uranium mining (1) US foreign policy (2) US support for Israel (2) vaccines work (1) Vandana Ramaswamy (1) VANISH (1) veepstakes (4) vice president (6) Vietnam War (7) VOE (1) volunteers (6) vote packing (1) voter education (2) voter ID (1) voter intimidation (2) voter mobilization (1) voter registration (12) voter suppression (9) voter turnout (8) voter-owned elections (1) voters (7) voters for obama (2) voting (1) voting problems (1) voting rights (1) vp (1) Waldenbooks (2) Wall Street (2) walter mondale (1) war (6) war in iraq (5) war on terror (4) war on women (1) war profits (1) War Resisters League (1) war toys (1) war weary (1) waste (2) waterboarding (1) wealth (2) white supremacy (3) Whittle Communications (1) Winona LaDuke (3) Wisconsin (2) women (1) Woodrow Wilson (1) Woodstock (1) workers (1) workplace discrimination (1) World War One (1) xenophobia (2) Yippie! (1) Yitzhak Rabin (1) you're fired (1) young voters (1) youth (1) youth empowerment (2) youtube (1) Yusef Hawkins (1) Zionism (2)

Even More Outrage via Leftweets.org

Twitter Outrage News Feed